Log in

Capital structure in an option-theoretic setting

  • Original Article
  • Published:
SN Business & Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper presents an option-theoretic framework for considering capital structure issues. The framework allows for illustration of the effect of leverage using numerical examples that are objective within the model. That is, once the framework is established and reasonable parameter estimates are made, there remains no subjectivity in the effects the model illustrates. As a result, the outcome of this paper amounts to a benchmark case against which one can consider the effects on value and cost of capital should real world conditions deviate from the assumptions we make. We do not conduct empirical tests. While our setup can reproduce earlier theoretical results, it also finds exceptions to the finding that the value curve is concave, as is often referenced in other studies. In addition, we demonstrate that choosing the level of leverage to maximize value is not always equivalent to choosing the level of leverage to minimize cost of capital. Finally, we compare outcomes for weighted average cost of capital based on state-claim expected returns to outcomes for weighted average cost of capital when it is calculated as taught in business schools. We find that in some settings there is a significant difference between the outcomes. Thus, our results suggest that traditional determinations of weighted average cost of capital in high leverage situations may produce misleading results, and that this caution ought to be part of the pedagogical agenda.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Germany)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Availability of data and material

No data use used in the performance of this work.

Code availability

The code used to generate outcomes presented in this work is freely available upon request.

Notes

  1. Other option pricing platforms could be used, such as Merton (1976), Heston (1993) or Christoffersen (2015), but the basic narrative would not differ materially and the algebraic proofs would be more difficult, hence our decision to use Black and Scholes (1973). For completeness, we also cite Merton (1973).

  2. It is acknowledged that there are other settings in which the deviation of expected return on debt from nominal return on debt can be studied.

  3. Stiglitz (1974) considers the interaction of corporations and the household sector, but his analysis is conducted in the absence of both corporate and personal taxation, and in the absence of the possibility of bankruptcy (see Stiglitz, 1974, p. 857). As a result, it contributes only tangentially to the current discussion.

  4. Miller (1977) acknowledges that others had also considered the issue, including Farrar and Selwyn (1967), Myers (1967), Stapleton (1972), Stiglitz (1973) and Black (1971, 1973).

  5. For a more up to date consideration of bankruptcy costs see Hoelle (2010) or Davydenko et al. (2012).

  6. Note that we conducted our entire analysis in a Cox et al. (1979) setting in which the state space is discrete and the distributional assumptions over asset prices and returns are a very close approximation to the distributional assumptions in a Black/Scholes/Merton setting and our results go through identically in that setup.

  7. We prefer the term ‘reorganization costs’ because we see them as being triggered by financial distress, which may or may not involve legal bankruptcy (i.e. a firm in proceedings under a bankruptcy statute). We do not think ‘bankruptcy’ is a particularly good synonym for financial distress because it leaves open to interpretation whether the user means legal bankruptcy or financial distress without legal bankruptcy.

  8. Hirshleifer (1966, P. 25) refers to bankruptcy penalties but does not reflect them explicitly in the presented analysis.

  9. Ross et al. (2019) comments on this style of analysis on page 645, referring to it as “the extended pie model”.

  10. To be specific, we imagine the formation of a firm at time t, the ongoing efforts of the firm over the period Tt following which the firm has a terminal cash outcome or payoff available for distribution to claimants of VT.

  11. Although simple and somewhat obvious the algebra is presented in Appendix 1.

  12. This simplification also makes it easier to model a switch between triggering reorganization fees if: (a) \({V}_{T}\) is less than the bond’s face value; versus, (b) if \({V}_{T}\) is less than the bond’s face value plus interest owing at T.

  13. Capital losses are more fully specified below. It is acknowledged that this approach assumes that there is sufficient income available from other sources to make the shelter useful.

  14. The fact that it is necessary to make this assumption is not terribly debilitating in our approach because we are not seeking to determine what \(\mu\) ought to be. Rather, we are seeking to determine how a given return \(\mu\) is carved up among contingent claims depending on the level of leverage.

  15. These are the usual Black/Scholes/Merton expressions. They are presented collectively as Eq. (13) in Black and Scholes (1973, p. 644). The put expression is also the usual Black/Scholes/Merton expression and follows from put-call parity. Further, we assume there is no continuously paid dividend during the life of the equity claim.

  16. The call pricing expression and d1 and d2 are the usual Black/Scholes/Merton expressions. They are presented collectively as Eq. (13) in Black and Scholes (1973, p. 644). The put expression is also the usual Black/Scholes/Merton expression and follows from put-call parity. Further, we assume there is no continuously paid dividend during the life of the equity claim.

  17. The amount available for dividends to shareholders is \(\left( {1 - \tau } \right)Call\left( {A_{t} e^{{q\left( {T - t} \right)}} + B_{t} } \right)\) In an integrated tax system, tax paid in the corporation as added back to dividends to create the tax base for the shareholders. Tax payable by applying the tax rate on dividends to this tax base is reduced by the amount of tax paid in the corporation, leaving the shareholders to pay the balance. When the tax rate on profits in the corporation is set equal to the tax rate on dividends to shareholders, the tax position of the shareholder after both corporate income tax and personal tax on dividends is as shown in Eq. (9).

  18. In a Black/Scholes/Merton setting, the value of a put is specified as \({\text{Put}}_{t}={e}^{-r\left(T-t\right)}KN\left(-d2\right)-{V}_{t}N(-d1)\) where r is the continuously compounded riskless interest rate, t is the current time and T is the maturity date of the option, K is the strike price, \({d}_{1} \mathrm{and} {d}_{2}\) are as specified in Black and Scholes (1973), page 644, and \(N\left(\bullet \right)\) is the cumulative normal density function. The second term of the option pricing expression is desired discounted expectation such that \(Reorg={\alpha e}^{r(T-t)}E\left({V}_{T}|{V}_{T}<D\right)=\alpha {V}_{t}N(-d1)\)

  19. As stated earlier, it is acknowledged that there are other settings in which the deviation of expected return on debt from nominal return on debt can be studied.

References

  • Ang JS, Chua JH, McConnell JJ (1982) The administrative costs of corporate bankruptcy: a note. J Finance 37(1):219–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antill S, Grenadier SR (2019) Optimal capital structure and bankruptcy choice: dynamic bargaining versus liquidation. J Finance Econ 133(1):198–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arditti FD (1973) The weighted average cost of capital: some questions on its definition

  • Bennett RL (2001) Evaluating the adequacy of the deposit insurance fund: a credit-risk modeling approach. FDIC working paper 2001–02. http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/working/wp2001_02/workingpaper2001-02.pdf. Accessed Jan 2021

  • Black F (1971) Taxes and capital market equilibrium. Working paper no. 21A, Associates in Finance, Belmont, Massachusetts, (Mimeo)

  • Black F (1973) Taxes and capital market equilibrium under uncertainty. Working paper no. 21B, Chicago, (Mimeo)

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Polit Econ 81(3):637–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan MJ, Schwartz ES (1978) Corporate income taxes, valuation, and the problem of optimal capital structure. J Bus 51(1):103–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christoffersen P, Feunou B, Jeon Y (2015) Option valuation with observable volatility and jump dynamics. J Bank Finance 61:S101–S120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbae D, D’Erasmo P (2021) Reorganization or liquidation: bankruptcy choice and firm dynamics. Rev Econ Stud 88(5):2239–2274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ross SA, Rubinstein M (1979) Option pricing: a simplified approach. J Finance Econ 7(3):229–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D'Amato A (2021) Capital structure and macroeconomic conditions: a review of the literature and a research agenda. In: Marleau K (ed) Advances in capital structure research, pp 33–62

  • Davydenko SA, Strebulaev IA, Zhao X (2012) A market-based study of the cost of default. Rev Financ Stud 25(10):2959–2999

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeAngelo H, Masulis R (1980) Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation. J Finance Econ 8:3–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dev A, Li S, Wan Z (2006) An analytical model for the FDIC deposit insurance premium. SSRN working paper series. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=964622

  • Farrar D, Selwyn LL (1967) Taxes, corporate policy, and returns to investors. Natl Tax J 20(4):444–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Leary MT (2011) A review of empirical capital structure research and directions for the future. Annu Rev Financ Econ 3(1):309–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston SL (1993) A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options. Rev Financ Stud 6(2):327–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer J (1966) Investment decision under uncertainty: applications of the state-preference approach. Q J Econ 80(2):252–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoelle M (2010) Bankruptcy and transaction costs in general financial models. Doctoral Dissertation, University of Pennsylvania

  • Khan S, Bashir U, Islam MS (2020) Determinants of capital structure of banks: evidence from the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia. Int J Islam Middle Eastern Finance Manag 14(2):268–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kraus A, Litzenberger RH (1973) A state-preference model of optimal financial leverage. J Finance 28(4):911–922

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar S, Colombage S, Rao P (2017) Research on capital structure determinants: a review and future directions. Int J Manag Finance 13(2):106–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumar S, Sureka R, Colombage S (2020) Capital structure of SMEs: a systematic literature review and bibliometric analysis. Manag Rev Q 70(4):535–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuritzkes A, Schuermann T, Weiner SM (2005) Deposit insurance and risk management of the US banking system: what is the loss distribution faced by the FDIC? J Financ Serv Res 27(3):217–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maccario A, Sironi A, Zazzara C (2004) Credit risk models: an application to deposit insurance pricing. SDA BOCCONI research division working paper no. 03-84

  • Martinez LB, Scherger V, Guercio MB (2018) SMEs capital structure: trade-off or pecking order theory: a systematic review. J Small Bus Enterp Dev 26(1):105–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1973) Theory of rational option pricing. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 4(1):141–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1976) Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. J Finance Econ 3(1–2):125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller MH (1977) Debt and taxes. J Finance 32(2):261–275

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller M (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48(3):261–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller MH (1963) Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. Am Econ Rev 53(3):433–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC (1967) Taxes, corporate financial policy and the return to investors: comment. Natl Tax J 20(4):455–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robichek AA, Myers SC (1966) Problems in the theory of optimal capital structure. J Financ Quant Anal 1(2):1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross SA (2005) Capital structure and the cost of capital. J Appl Finance 15(1):5–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross SA, Westerfield RW, Jordan BD, Roberts GS, Pandes JA, Holloway TA (2019) Fundamentals of corporate finance, 10th Canadian edition. McGraw-Hill Ryerson

  • Shoaib K, Yasushi S (2015) Capital structure and managerial ownership: evidence from Pakistan. Bus Econ Horizons 11(1232–2016–101199):131–142

  • Shoaib K, Yasushi S (2016) Ownership and capital structure of Pakistani non financial firms. Financ Internet Q 12(1):57–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stapleton RC (1972) Taxes, the cost of capital and the theory of investment. Econ J 82:1273–1292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (1973) Taxation, corporate financial policy, and the cost of capital. J Public Econ 2(1):1–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (1974) On the irrelevance of corporate financial policy. Am Econ Rev 64(6):851–866

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundaresan S (2013) A review of Merton’s model of the firm’s capital structure with its wide applications. Annu Rev Financ Econ 5(1):21–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakor AV (2011) Fifty years since modigliani and miller: is capital structure really relevant for firm value? Available at SSRN 1769009

  • Warner JB (1977) Bankruptcy costs: some evidence. J Finance 32(2):337–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • USGA: United States General Accounting Office (1988) Failed Banks: FDIC’s asset liquidation operations. Document GAO/GDD 88-132. Report to the Chairman, Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate. September 1988. http://www.gao.gov/assets/150/147018.pdf

  • USGA: United States General Accounting Office (1994) Bank resolutions. Report to congressional committees GAO/GGD 94–107. https://www.gao.gov/products/ggd-94-107

Download references

Funding

No specific research funding was provided or used in the performance of this work.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael L. McIntyre.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

There are no apparent conflicts of interest with any other party.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 36 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

McIntyre, M.L. Capital structure in an option-theoretic setting. SN Bus Econ 2, 109 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s43546-022-00263-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s43546-022-00263-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation