Log in

Veto players and foreign aid provision

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates how the political institutions of developed economies influence their foreign assistance. Specifically, we argue that the number of effective veto players has a negative effect on the volume of aid provision. To provide foreign assistance, the incumbent government in a donor country must have unanimous support from all effective veto players in policy making. Thus, it has more barriers to overcome when the polity is characterized by many and preference-wise heterogeneous veto players. By examining the official development assistance outflows of 27 OECD countries for the period of 1977–2006, we find empirical patterns that corroborate our argument.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Thailand)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In fact, many apparently idealistic foreign aid programs can be explained as the result of rational calculus intended to boost the domestic popularity of the incumbent government. For instance, the impression of pursuing global equality associated with such programs could be an instrument used by an extreme left-wing government to satisfy the ideological demands of its domestic base.

  2. To facilitate cross-national and over-time comparisons, currency-related variables are PPP- and inflation-adjusted in the present study. The corresponding convertor and deflator are from the Penn World Table Version 7.0 (Heston et al. 2011).

  3. Henisz (2000, 2002) elaborates on all the technical nuances involved in gauging the constraining effect of veto players on policy outcome. In particular, Table 2 of Henisz (2000) lists every five-year average value of veto players for 157 countries for the period 1960–1994. Table A2 of Henisz (2002) further lists every 10-year average value of veto players for the same pool of nations back to 1800. Thus, readers might take a look at these articles for how the measure varies both across and within nations.

  4. It is calculated based on the countries’ iron and steel production, military expenditure, military personnel, primary energy consumption, total population and urban population, which is measured as the population living in cities of more than 100,000 people.

  5. It is important to note that veto players, regime type, and FDI outflows are all significant for the post-Cold War subsample but not for the Cold War subsample. This is a piece of evidence in support of our argument.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Dollar, D. (2000). Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 22–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., & Smith, A. (2007). Foreign aid and policy concessions. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51(2), 251–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid. Policies and Growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong, A., & Gradstein, M. (2008). What Determines Foreign Aid? The Donors’ Perspective. Journal of Development Economics, 87(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Dollar, D. (2002). Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction. European Economic Review, 46(8), 1457–1500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalgaard, C.-J., Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2004). On the Empirics of Foreign Aid and Growth. The Economic Journal, 114, 191–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Derbyshire, J. D., & Derbyshire, I. (1996). Political systems of the world. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2008). The curse of aid. Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3), 169–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2003). Can foreign aid buy growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3), 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W., Levine, R., & Roodman, D. (2004). Aid, policies, and growth: a comment. American Economic Review, 94(3), 774–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganghof, S. (2003). Promises and Pitfalls of Veto Player Analysis. Swiss Political Science Review, 9(2), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin, K. (1991). Foreign aid after the Cold War. Development and Change, 22(4), 645–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurr, T. (1996). Polity III: Political structures and regime change. Boulder, CO: Center for Comparative Politics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harms, P., & Lutz, M. (2006). Aid, governance and private foreign investment. The Economic Journal, 116(513), 773–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46(6), 1251–1272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Headey, D. (2008). Geopolitics and the effect of foreign aid on economic growth: 1970–2001. Journal of International Development, 20(2), 161–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2000). The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2002). The Institutional Environment for Infrastructure Investment. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(2), 355–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2010). The political constraint index dataset. http://www.management.wharton.upenn.edu/henisz/POLCON/ContactInfo.html.

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2011). Penn world table version 7.0. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania. https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/.

  • Hook, S., & Guang, Z. (1998). Japan’s aid policy since the Cold War: Rhetoric and reality. Asian Survey, 38(11), 1051–1066.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, S. J., Lee, H., & Park, B. (2011). Does Korea Follow Japan in Foreign Aid? Relationships between Aid and Foreign Investment. Japan and the World Economy, 23(1), 19–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimura, H., & Todo, Y. (2010). Is Foreign Aid a Vanguard of Foreign Direct Investment? World Development, 38(4), 482–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (2004). Does Foreign Aid Promote Democracy? International Studies Quarterly, 48(1), 251–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundborg, P. (1998). Foreign Aid and International Supports as a Gift Exchange. Economics and Politics, 10(2), 127–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maizels, A., & Nissanke, M. (1984). Motivations for aid to develo** countries. World Development, 12(9), 879–900.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Pevehouse, J. (2007). Vetoing Cooperation: the Impact of Veto Players on Preferential Trading Arrangements. British Journal of Political Science, 37(3), 403–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Pevehouse, J. (2008). Democracy, Veto players and the Depth of Regional Integration. World Economy, 31(1), 67–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M., & Jaggers, K. (2009). Polity IV project. http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.html.

  • McGillivray, M., Feeny, S., Hermes, N., & Lensink, R. (2006). Controversies over the impact of development aid. Journal of International Development, 18(7), 1031–1050.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinlay, R., & Little, R. (1979). The US aid relationship: A test of the recipient need and the donor interest models. Political Studies, 27(2), 236–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meernik, J., Krueger, E., & Poe, S. (1998). Testing models of US foreign policy: Foreign aid during and after the Cold War. The Journal of Politics, 60(1), 63–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2010) International development statistics. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/50/17/5037721.html.

  • Rae, D., & Taylor, M. (1970). The analysis of political cleavages. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raffer, K., & Singer, H. (1996). The foreign aid business. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2007). Anarchy of numbers: Aid, development, and cross-country empirics. The World Bank Economic Review, 21(2), 255–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schraeder, P., Hook, S., & Taylor, B. (1998). Clarifying the foreign aid puzzle. World Politics, 50(2), 294–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singer, D. (1987). Reconstructing the correlates of war dataset on material capabilities of states, 1816–1985. International Interactions, 14(2):115–132. http://www.correlatesofwar.org/COW2%20Data/Capabilities/nmc3-02.html.

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1999). Veto players and law production in parliamentary democracies. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 591–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2000). Veto players and institutional analysis. Governance, 13(4), 441–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2010). World development indicators. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator.

  • World Values Survey Association. (2009). World values survey 1981–2008. Madrid: ASEP/JDS. http://www.wvsevsdb.com/wvs/WVSData.jsp.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yu Wang.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Wang, Y., **, S. Veto players and foreign aid provision. Const Polit Econ 24, 43–56 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-012-9131-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-012-9131-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation