Log in

Currency concentration in sovereign debt, exchange rate cyclicality, and volatility in consumption

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

For emerging economies, borrowing abroad is a double-edged sword: it can buffer against adverse economic shocks and smooth their domestic consumption; however, it can also amplify volatility in consumption, depending on the currency in which the debt is denominated and cyclicality in the borrower’s exchange rate. We empirically investigate the nexus among external debt portfolios, exchange rate cyclicality, and volatility in consumption of low- and middle-income countries. Since 1980, many countries have concentrated their external debt portfolios’ currency composition. By constructing debt-weighted effective exchange rates, we find that currency concentration magnifies exchange rate pro-cyclicality, making domestic consumption more volatile when national income fluctuates. Our results endorse diversifying the currency composition of external debt to mitigate the negative consequences of “original sin.”

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recently some emerging market economies improved their ability to borrow abroad in their home currencies (Arslanalp & Tsuda, 2014; Du & Schreger, 2016). Nonetheless, original sin remains generally prevalent among LMICs.

  2. Several studies (Claessens, 1992; Dodd & Spiegel, 2005; Fujii, 2017) endorse a portfolio perspective when considering the currency composition of indebtedness among emerging economies.

  3. For consistency and comparability of results, we limited our sample to countries with effective observations of currency denominations, exchange rates, and output for pre-EUR and EUR periods.

  4. An exception is China during 2016 and 2017 when the Chinese yuan (CNY) comprised 10.92% of the SDR basket.

  5. The “synthetic EUR” share in Figs. 1 and 2 connects the two series, i.e., the sum of debt denominated in DEM and FRF for 1980–2000 and the EUR for 2001–2017.

  6. We regressed foreign currency shares along a constant and time trend to see if the time trend’s coefficient is statistically significant at the 5% level (positive or negative).

  7. Until 1980, SDRs contained 16 currencies with weights changing annually. Their composition was revised during 1981 to feature the USD, DEM, FRF, JPY, and GBP with weights revised every 5 years. The EUR replaced the DEM and FRF during 1999, and CNY joined the basket during 2016. For 1980, we use the weights applicable in 1981.

  8. A rise in the value of DEER indicates effective depreciation in country i's currency.

  9. We used GDP-deflator inflation rates from the World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

  10. Another contributing factor may be the dollarization that countries such as Ecuador and El Salvador adopted during the 2000s.

  11. See Cordella and Gupta (2015) for an analysis of nominal effective exchange rate cyclicality of advanced and emerging market economies.

  12. The literature concerning this contentious topic is too voluminous to cite here. See Jappelli and Pistaferri (2010) for a comprehensive review.

  13. Highlighting the drawbacks of the Hodrik–Prescott filter, Hamilton (2018) proposes a better alternative that uses the linear population projection of yt+h on a constant and p most recent values of y at date t. For the annual frequency data, we set the parameter values as h = 2 and p = 2, following the suggestions of Hamilton (2018).

  14. Savings to GDP are lagged to avert simultaneity with consumption.

  15. See the Data Appendix for the list of sampled countries.

  16. If perfectly smoothed, consumption is constant and the intercepts are 0. The effect of capital account openness reduces the positive intercepts of exchange rate regimes.

  17. The exchange rate regime dummies we included in estimating Eqs. (5) and (6) capture only the regime-specific consumption growth that remain constant irrespective of income changes.

  18.  ± 2% is the standard width of exchange rate bands adopted by the regimes in the rigid category. We also used 5% as an alternative threshold to find qualitatively similar results.

  19. Unlike RDEER, a rise in REER indicates real appreciation for domestic countries.

  20. Fujii (2017) argues that correspondence between the currency compositions of external debt and international trade have important implications. Specifically, the author finds that LMICs with more accordant debt–trade currency compositions tend to have growth advantages over those without.

References

  • Alfaro, L., & Kanczuk, F. (2009). Optimal reserve management and sovereign debt. Journal of International Economics, 77, 23–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arslanalp, S., & Tsuda, T. (2014). Tracking global demand for emerging market sovereign debt. IMF Economic Review, 3, 430–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus, D. K., Kehoe, P. J., & Kydland, F. E. (1992). International real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 745–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bengui, J., & Nguyen, Ha. (2016). Consumption baskets and currency choice in international borrowing. Journal of International Money and Finance, 67, 287–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleaney, M., & Gulcin Ozkan, F. (2011). The structure of public debt and the choice of exchange rate regime. Canadian Journal of Economics, 44, 325–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Pistaferri, L., & Preston, I. (2008). Consumption inequality and partial insurance. American Economic Review, 98, 1887–1921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bunn, P., Le Roux, J., Reinold, K., & Surico, P. (2018). The consumption response to positive and negative income shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics, 96, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burger, J. D., & Warnock, F. E. (2006). Local currency bond markets. IMF Staff Papers, 53, 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2003). Excessive dollar debt: Financial development and underinsurance. Journal of Finance, 58, 867–893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D. (1992). The buffer stock theory of saving: Some macroeconomic evidence. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 61–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D. (1994). How does future income affect consumption? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 111–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D. (2009). Precautionary saving and the marginal propensity to consume out of permanent income. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 780–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81, 163–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, S. (1992). The optimal currency composition of external debt: Theory and applications to Mexico and Brazil. World Bank Economic Review, 6, 503–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, S., Klingebiel, D., & Schmukler, S. L. (2007). Government bonds in domestic and foreign currency: The role of institutional and macroeconomic factors. Review of International Economics, 15, 370–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordella, T., & Gupta, P. (2015). What makes a currency procyclical? An empirical investigation. Journal of International Money and Finance, 55, 240–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (1991). Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica, 59, 1221–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dodd, R., & Spiegel, S (2005). Up from sin: A portfolio approach to financial salvation. G-24 Discussion Paper Series, n.34, United Nations.

  • Du, W., & Schreger, J. (2016). Local currency sovereign risk. Journal of Finance, 71, 1027–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., & Gersovitz, M. (1981). Debt with potential repudiation: Theoretical and empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies, 48, 289–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., & Panizza, U. (2005). The pain of original sin. In B. Eichengreen & R. Husmann (Eds.), Other People’s Money: Debt denomination and financial instability in emerging economies. University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., Hausmann, R., & Panizza, U. (2007). Currency mismatches, debt intolerance, and the original sin: why they are not the same and why it matters. In S. Edwards (Ed.), Capital controls and capital flows in emerging economies: policies, practices and consequences. NBER, University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel, C., & Park, J. J. (2022). Debauchery and original sin: The currency composition of sovereign debt. Journal of the European Economic Association, 20, 1095–1144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flavin, M. A. (1981). The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 974–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujii, E. (2017). External debt and international trade: Another mismatch. In Y.-W. Cheung & F. Westermann (Eds.), International currency exposure. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gopinath, G., & Stein, J. C. (2021). Banking, trade, and the making of a dominant currency. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 136, 783–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gumus, I. (2013). Debt denomination and default risk in emerging markets. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 171, 1070–1095.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. D. (2018). Why you should never use the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Review of Economics and Statistics, 100, 831–843.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., & Panizza, U. (2003). On the determinants of original sin: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Money and Finance, 22, 957–990.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilzetzki, E., Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2019). Exchange arrangements entering the 21st century: Which anchor will hold? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134, 599–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli, T., & Pistaferri, L. (2010). The consumption response to changes in income. Annual Review of Economics, 2, 479–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky, G. L., Reinhart, C. M., & Végh, C. A. (2004). When it rains, it pours: Procyclical capital flows and macroeconomic policies. NBER Chapters. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Vol. 19, pp. 11–82). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Korinek, A. (2011). Foreign currency debt, risk premia and macroeconomic volatility. European Economic Review, 55, 371–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose, M. A., Nagle, P., Ohnsorge, F., & Sugawara, N. (2019). Global waves of debt: Causes and consequences. The World Bank Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52, 1131–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogrokhina, O., & Rodriguez, C. M. (2018). The role of inflation targeting in international debt denomination in develo** countries. Journal of International Economics, 114, 116–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakko, M. R. (1998). Characterizing cross-country consumption correlations. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 169–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panizza, U., & Presbitero, A. F. (2014). Public debt and economic growth: Is there a causal effect? Journal of Macroeconomics, 41, 21–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, J. M., & Thyne, C. L. (2011). Global instances of coups from 1950 to 2010: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 48, 249–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranciere, R., Tornell, A., & Vamvakidis, A. (2010). Currency mismatch, systemic risk and growth in emerging Europe. Economic Policy, 25, 597–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2010). Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review, 100, 573–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talvi, E., Carlos, A., & Végh, C. (2005). Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy in develo** countries. Journal of Development Economics, 78, 156–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research is supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 18K01715. The author is grateful to two anonymous referees and an associate editor of the journal for helpful comments and suggestions. He also thanks **ngwang Qian, Isabelle Mejean, workshop participants at Université Catholique de Louvain, and seminar participants at the Center for Risk Research of Shiga University for helpful comments on early versions of the paper. All errors are solely the author’s.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eiji Fujii.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 20 KB)

Data Appendix

Data Appendix

1.1 Sources

Currency composition of external debt: World Bank’s International Debt Statistics.

Exchange rate regime indicators: Ilzetzki et al. (2019)a

Index of capital account openness: Chinn and Ito (2006)b

Incidents of coups d’état: Powell and Thyne (2011)c

Other macroeconomic and external account variables: World Bank’s World Development Indicators and International Monetary Fund’s International Financial statistics.

Notes:

aWe downloaded the regime index from http://www.carmenreinhart.com/data/ and https://www.ilzetzki.com/irr-data. We use coarse classifications.

bThe index is based on binary dummy variables that codify restrictions on cross-border financial transactions reported in IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. It is the first principal component of the original variables on regulatory controls over current or capital account transactions, the existence of multiple exchange rates, and requirements of surrendering export proceeds.

cWe use “Dataset 2: Coup Attempts, 1950–Present” in Powell and Thyne (2011). Coups are illegal and overt attempts by the military or other elites within the state apparatus to unseat a sitting executive. Our dummy variable equals 1 for successful and unsuccessful coup attempts because they indicate political instability.

1.2 Frequency

Annual for all series.

1.3 Sample periods

The primary sample period is 1980–2017. The pre-EUR and EUR sub-periods are 1980–2000 and 2001–2017, respectively. Depending on data availability, some countries have smaller samples.

Euro: exchange rate 1999–2017; currency composition 2001–2017.

Deutsche mark and French franc: exchange rate 1973–1998; currency composition 1973–2000; Exchange rates for 1999 and 2000 are set to €1 = 1.95583 DEM and €1 = 6.55957 FRF.

Synthetic EUR: 1980–2017, of which the 1980–2000 period is calculated by the weighted sum of DEM- and FRF-denominated debt.

1.4 Sampled countries

Our sample consists of low-, lower-middle-, and upper-middle-income countries listed in the WDI, for which data for the currency composition of external debt, exchange rates, and GDP growth rates are available for pre-EUR and EUR periods. The primary sample includes 106 countries (24 low-income and 82 middle-income countries) listed in the income stratification section.

The Sect. 5 analyses reduce the effective number of sampled countries through limited data to construct variables for estimations. More specifically, for the estimates in Tables 4, 5, and 6, the effective number of countries is 86. The following countries were dropped for data constraints: Angola, Central African Republic, China, Dominica, Ethiopia, Fiji, Gambia, Grenada, Guyana, St. Lucia, the Maldives, Malaysia, Panama, Papua New Guinea, the Solomon Islands, Tonga, Vanuatu, Samoa, Yemen, and Zambia.

For the estimates in Table 7, the sample consists of the following 37 countries whose REER data are available: Albania, Armenia, Burundi, Bulgaria, Bolivia, Brazil, Bhutan, Cote d'Ivoire, Cameroon, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Algeria, Gabon, Georgia, Ghana, Iran, Lesotho, Morocco, Moldova, Mexico, Malawi, Nigeria, Nicaragua, Pakistan, the Philippines, Paraguay, Romania, Russia, Sierra Leone, Togo, Tunisia, Uganda, Ukraine, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, and Venezuela.

1.5 Income stratification

Low-income countries comprise the following 24 countries: Burundi, Benin, Burkina Faso, Central African Republic, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Comoros, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Guinea, Gambia, Guinea-Bissau, Haiti, Madagascar, Mozambique, Malawi, Niger, Nepal, Rwanda, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Chad, Togo, Tanzania, and Uganda.

Lower-middle-income countries comprise the following 42 countries: Angola, Armenia, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Bhutan, Cote d'Ivoire, Cameroon, Republic of the Congo, Cabo Verde, Egypt, Georgia, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Indonesia, India, Jordan, Kenya, Kyrgyz Republic, Cambodia, Lao, Sri Lanka, Lesotho, Morocco, Moldova, Mongolia, Mauritania, Nigeria, Nicaragua, Pakistan, the Philippines, Papua New Guinea, Sudan, the Solomon Islands, El Salvador, Tajikistan, Tunisia, Ukraine, Vietnam, Vanuatu, Yemen, and Zambia.

Upper-middle-income countries comprise the following 40 countries: Albania, Azerbaijan, Bulgaria, Belarus, Belize, Brazil, Botswana, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Algeria, Ecuador, Fiji, Gabon, Grenada, Guyana, Iran, Jamaica, Kazakhstan, Lebanon, St. Lucia, the Maldives, Mexico, Mauritius, Malaysia, Panama, Peru, Paraguay, Romania, Russia, Serbia, Thailand, Tonga, Turkey, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Venezuela, Samoa, and South Africa (Figs. 1, 2, 3).

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fujii, E. Currency concentration in sovereign debt, exchange rate cyclicality, and volatility in consumption. Rev World Econ 160, 169–192 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-023-00493-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-023-00493-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation