Log in

Immigration, wages, and employment under informal labor markets

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the labor market impacts of the Venezuelan immigration in Colombia. Exploiting spatial variation in exposure, I find a negative effect on native wages driven by the informal sector (where immigrants are concentrated) and a reduction in native employment in the formal sector (where the minimum wage binds for many workers). To explain this, I build a model in which a firm substitutes formal for informal labor in response to lower informal wages. Consistent with the model’s predictions, I document that the decrease in formal employment is driven by small firms that use both labor types in production and by workers earning the minimum wage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The main datasets used in this paper are publicly available on the official webpage of DANE. They can be downloaded in their https://microdatos.dane.gov.co/index.php/catalog/central/about repository.

Notes

  1. The supply of migrants is measured as working-age Venezuelans over working-age natives.

  2. The trade-off between wages and employment in the face of migration shocks goes back to Grossman (1982).

  3. In addition, to alleviate concerns with the exclusion restriction, I further show that trade shocks arising from the Venezuelan crisis are not particularly relevant in the post-treatment period, as most trade adjustments happened before the arrival of migrants.

  4. Throughout this paper, wages can refer to labor income as they contain both the labor income of self-employed and wages of employees.

  5. In fact, Caruso et al. (2021) find the most negative wage elasticity (\(-\)7.6%) relative to the existing migration literature cited by Dustmann et al. (2016). In Appendix G, I show that the difference between the wage estimates of this paper and that one is driven by the sample period they analyze (until 2017) and the empirical specification they choose (panel data regression). This motivates, in part, the analysis performed in this paper.

  6. Edo (2020) finds for the Algerian inflow in France that a one pp increase of repatriates lowered native wages by between 1.3 and 2%.

  7. The event study design is motivated by the fact that the static coefficient in most previous studies comes from a panel IV regression that may be interpreted as a weighted average of treatment effects. The issue is that these weights may even be negative, for instance, because the timing of treatment varies across groups or because the treatment is continuous (De Chaisemartin and d’Haultfoeuille 2020; Goodman-Bacon 2021). Moreover, this specification needs the PTA, among other assumptions, to yield consistent estimates. Caruso et al. (2021) provide evidence of the lack of correlation between migration rates in 1973 and 2005 with present outcomes, yet the authors do not analyze pre-treatment data before the immigration shock. In that sense, Morales-Zurita et al. (2020) use recent pre-treatment data to find null correlations between past settlements and migration flows between 2013 and 2015, but they do not study if their instrument predicts economic outcomes during the same years. Finally, Lebow (2024) studies pre-trends for different outcomes between 2013 and 2015 to find significant differences in unemployment and labor force participation rates before the immigration shock. Therefore, these studies need to account for possible differences in pre-trends.

  8. For instance, Morales-Zurita et al. (2020), Caruso et al. (2021), and Lebow (2024) include in their post-treatment period the years before 2015. But these years of low immigration rates coincide with the massive drop in cross-border trade with Venezuela (as shown later in Appendix Figure F.1), resulting in a source of bias in their estimates.

  9. It also helps to distinguish the possible effects of the change in the legal status of Venezuelans during the post-treatment years.

  10. In July 2018, the salient president of Colombia, Juan Manuel Santos, unexpectedly announced the creation of a special permit to work for all Venezuelans registered in the Administrative Record of Venezuelan Migrants (RAMV, by its acronym in Spanish).

  11. The PEP was initially valid for 90 days and could be renewed for up to 2 years.

  12. In Ecuador, Olivieri et al. (2021) find that providing work permits to Venezuelan workers would increase their average earnings.

  13. Moreover, I include 2011 and 2012 in the analysis for additional pre-treatment periods, assuming all survey respondents were Colombian.

  14. Nearly 443,000 individual records were gathered from April 6 to June 8 in 2018 at different points in all the territory. It was an optional and go-to-the-registration-point kind of survey for undocumented Venezuelans.

  15. A recent paper by Lebow (2022) summarizes the differences in the wage effects of immigration in Colombian studies.

  16. By construction, \(\beta _{2015}=0\) and all coefficients \(\beta _t \in T=\{2011,...,2019\}\) measure the effect relative to 2015.

  17. In the Appendix F, I show that results are almost identical if I use a denominator from the GEIH survey in 2015 (see Figures F.3a and F.3b).

  18. Moreover, the survey weights were built using the 2005 census, and its reference frame was not updated until the 2018 census, creating additional uncertainty when constructing migration shares using the survey.

  19. The use of a time-invariant treatment variable is particularly attractive in settings in which the intensity of the treatment increases proportionally across regions over time, i.e., in which the measure of exposure for different years differs only in scale. As shown in Fig. 2b, this is the case in my setting.

  20. Regression weights are typically used to estimate population average partial effects. However, Solon et al. (2015) state that this is not straightforward, bringing up arguments for using or not using the weights. In any case, when using regression weights, I find more negative estimates for native wages and more positive ones for employment (see Appendix Figure F.6a), and also results by the formal and informal sectors hold (see Appendix Figure F.7a).

  21. Jaeger (2007) and Borjas (2001) have pointed out that immigrants tend to settle in areas that offer the best economic opportunities for the skills they provide.

  22. The data for the outcomes is available to 24 departments, not to all 33 in the country. The missing nine departments, mostly located in the Amazonia and Orinoquia regions, only account for 2.8% of Colombia’s total population, according to the 2018 census.

  23. As a robustness check, I develop the test proposed in Goldsmith-Pinkham et al. (2020) to calculate the weights of the distance instrument, namely the Rotemberg weights, of the overall coefficient. I decompose the instrument into 15 shares arising from the different origin cities of migrants in Venezuela to determine which of them gets more weight in the overall estimate. This exercise yields that Maracaibo and San Cristóbal concentrate 0.7 of the weights, which sum up to 1. In fact, those cities are closer to the border with Colombia; hence, effectively, the instrument compares cities closer to the border with those further away. To name some characteristics of these migrants, Maracaibo is an industrial city focusing on oil extraction, while San Cristóbal relies more on the service and commerce sector.

  24. For employment, the pre-trends are insignificant only for the distance instrument.

  25. The first step to evaluate the exogeneity of the two instruments and possible heterogeneous effects is to perform a Hansen J test for over-identifying restrictions. In this case, I use both instruments in the first-stage regression 5 to find that the null hypothesis of the instruments being exogenous is not rejected.

  26. In practice, for instrumenting the interaction of year dummies with the immigration shock of Eq. 1, I interact the instruments with year dummies.

  27. Recently, Lee et al. (2022) argue for a higher F-statistic in the first stage, exactly a value of around 104.7. In this case, the distance instrument’s F-statistic is 287.1, and the past settlements instrument’s F-statistic is 33.7.

  28. Instruments predict a higher pre-treatment coefficient in 2011, which does not seem to be a big problem since trends have been relatively stable after 2011. A joint F-test for coefficients from 2012 to 2014 yields a p-value between 0.24 and 0.27, depending on the instrument.

  29. The construction of the wage, or labor income, variable is shown in Appendix I. Importantly, it covers all types of labor income, including self-employed earnings.

  30. I do not combine both instruments in the first stage as the distance instrument captures all the predictive power of the past settlements instrument.

  31. Appendix Figure E.1b shows that when using \(\Delta M_{dt}\) as the explanatory variable, instead of the fixed \(\Delta M_{d,2018}\) from the census, the results of native employment are similar but with wider confidence intervals in 2017.

  32. For firms, formality is defined based on the payment of direct taxes. For workers, formality is defined based on the contribution to the health or pension system. The EMICRON survey only covers owners of firms with less than 10 workers.

  33. In this model, I abstract from the extensive margin followed by Ulyssea (2018) to take into account only the labor choices of a given formal firm (the intensive margin). This means the model does not account for the firm’s decision to register in the tax records (become a formal firm), as the goal is to model informality through the worker side and analyze changes of a representative firm.

  34. Fines for hiring workers informally may go up to 500 minimum wages and are enforced by the Ministry of Labor in Colombia.

  35. In this case, I assume for simplicity that the number of consumers grows at the same rate as the workforce, that is, what Borjas (2013) defines as product market neutrality.

  36. A model proposed by Kleemans and Magruder (2018) distinguishes between types of skills for formal and informal workers. The main findings are that if migration is highly skilled, there is a crowd-out effect of existing formal low-skilled workers (with formal wages staying constant) and that migration (of any skill type) will (weakly) decrease wages in the informal sector.

  37. In the working paper version of this paper, I extend this theoretical framework with a general equilibrium model that includes capital responses and differential labor supply functions of migrants and natives. A strong substitutability between labor types also predicts a decrease in formal employment in this model.

  38. Results are unaltered if I use the past settlement instrument or control for trade with Venezuela.

  39. Because the results are aggregated, this effect is capturing possible spillover effects between the two sectors, that is, workers moving from formal to informal employment or the other way.

  40. Appendix Figure D.1 shows similar wage estimates using more frequent time windows (quarters instead of years). Also, pre-trends are not significant in this specification,

  41. Though, Dustmann et al. (2022) discuss that regional wages arising from cross-sectional data jointly measure the selection of workers and changes in the price of labor. Thus, there can be a compositional bias in the wage estimates.

  42. Dividing the sample by industry and sector increases the sampling error considerably, so I focus only on the largest industries.

  43. Regarding formal wages, coefficients are insignificant for both firm sizes.

  44. Informal employment significantly increases for smaller firms but not as much to counteract the formal employment decrease.

  45. In comparison to Turkey, Altindag et al. (2020) find that the large refugee shock of Syrians boosted firm creation in the country, especially for those with foreign partnerships.

  46. I measure the average number of workers who report working in a given firm size category with a specific question from the GEIH survey.

  47. Another mechanism to be analyzed is the effect on the creation of informal firms not registered in tax records.

  48. This assumption aligns with most of the literature; for a discussion of the wage effects of immigration allowing for demand shifts, see Borjas (2013).

  49. I use native wage change in 2018 and not overall wage change to remove possible compositional bias from immigrants’ lower wages. If, instead of the total change in employment, I include in the numerator the change in native employment, I would be estimating the labor supply elasticity.

  50. In Italy, Guriev et al. (2019) find an elasticity of labor demand in the informal market of around \(-\)1, meaning a more elastic demand in this sector and close to the long-run one when it is possible to adjust capital.

  51. The effect is so large because salaried informal employment is a small subset of employment, whereas the immigration shock is the share of overall employment.

References

  • Akgündüz YE, Torun H (2020) Two and a half million Syrian refugees, tasks and capital intensity. J Dev Econ 145:102470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aksu E, Erzan R, Kırdar MG (2022) The impact of mass migration of Syrians on the Turkish labor market. Labour Econ 76:102183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altındağ O, Bakış O, Rozo SV (2020) Blessing or burden? Impacts of refugees on businesses and the informal economy. J Dev Econ 146:102490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji JG, Card D (1991) The effects of immigration on the labor market outcomes of less-skilled natives. In Immigration, trade, and the labor market. University of Chicago Press, pp 201–234

  • Angrist JD, Pischke J-S (2008) Mostly harmless econometrics: an empiricist’s companion. Princeton University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano-Bover J, San S (2020). The role of firms in the assimilation of immigrants. Available at SSRN 3594778

  • Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson GH (2021) On the persistence of the China shock. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Aydemir A, Borjas GJ (2011) Attenuation bias in measuring the wage impact of immigration. J Law Econ 29(1):69–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahar D, Ibáñez AM, Rozo SV (2021) Give me your tired and your poor: impact of a large-scale amnesty program for undocumented refugees. J Dev Econ 151:102652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2001) Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market? Brook Pap Econ Act 2001(1):69–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2006) Native internal migration and the labor market impact of immigration. J Hum Resourc 41(2):221–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2013) The analytics of the wage effect of immigration. IZA J Migr 2(1):1–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2017) The labor supply of undocumented immigrants. Labour Econ 46:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ, Grogger J, Hanson GH (2012) Comment: on estimating elasticities of substitution. J Eur Econ Assoc 10(1):198–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calderón-Mejía V, Ibáñez AM (2016) Labour market effects of migration-related supply shocks: evidence from internal refugees in Colombia. J Econ Geogr 16(3):695–713

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (1990) The impact of the Mariel boatlift on the Miami labor market. ILR Rev 43(2):245–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (2001) Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market impacts of higher immigration. J Law Econ 19(1):22–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Caruso G, Canon CG, Mueller V (2021) Spillover effects of the Venezuelan crisis: migration impacts in Colombia. Oxf Econ Pap 73(2):771–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceritoglu E, Yunculer HBG, Torun H, Tumen S (2017) The impact of Syrian refugees on natives? Labor market outcomes in Turkey: evidence from a quasi-experimental design. IZA J Labor Policy 6(1):1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemens J (2021) How do firms respond to minimum wage increases? Understanding the relevance of non-employment margins. J Econ Perspec 35(1):51–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbi R, Ferraz T, Narita R (2021). Internal migration and labor market adjustments in the presence of non-wage compensation. Technical report, Working paper

  • De Chaisemartin C, d’Haultfoeuille X (2020) Two-way fixed effects estimators with heterogeneous treatment effects. Am Econ Rev 110(9):2964–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Carpio XV, Wagner MC (2015) The impact of Syrian refugees on the Turkish labor market. World Bank policy research working paper. pp 7402

  • Delgado-Prieto L (2023) Immigration and worker responses across firms: evidence from administrative records in Colombia. Technical report, Working Paper, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

  • Dustmann C, Frattini T, Preston IP (2013) The effect of immigration along the distribution of wages. Rev Econ Stud 80(1):145–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Otten S, Schönberg U, Stuhler J (2022) Labor market effects of immigration - identification and interpretation. Technical report

  • Dustmann C, Schönberg U, Stuhler J (2016) The impact of immigration: why do studies reach such different results? J Econ Perspec 30(4):31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Schönberg U, Stuhler J (2017) Labor supply shocks, native wages, and the adjustment of local employment. Q J Econ 132(1):435–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edo A (2020) The impact of immigration on wage dynamics: evidence from the Algerian independence war. J Eur Econ Assoc 18(6):3210–3260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edo A, Rapoport H (2019) Minimum wages and the labor market effects of immigration. Labour Econ 61:101753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith-Pinkham P, Sorkin I, Swift H (2020) Bartik instruments: what, when, why, and how. Am Econ Rev 110(8):2586–2624

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman-Bacon A (2021) Difference-in-differences with variation in treatment timing. J Econometr

  • Grossman JB (1982) The substitutability of natives and immigrants in production. Rev Econ Stat 596–603

  • Gulek, A. (2022). Formal effects of informal labor supply: evidence from the Syrian refugees in Turkey. Available at SSRN 4264865

  • Guriev S, Speciale B, Tuccio M (2019) How do regulated and unregulated labor markets respond to shocks? Evidence from immigrants during the Great Recession. J Law Econ Org 35(1):37–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh DS (1996) Labor demand. Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2020). World Economic Outlook. Technical report, International Monetary Fund. Available on: https://www.imf.org/external/datamapper/profile/VEN/WEO (Last Accessed 20 June 2020)

  • IPUMS (2019) Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, International: Version 7.2 [dataset]. https://doi.org/10.18128/D020.V7.2

  • Jaeger D (2007) Green cards and the location choices of immigrants in the United States, 1971–2000. Res Labor Econ 27:131–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger DA, Ruist J, Stuhler J (2018) Shift-share instruments and the impact of immigration. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kleemans M, Magruder J (2018) Labour market responses to immigration: evidence from internal migration driven by weather shocks. Econ J 128(613):2032–2065

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lebow J (2022) The labor market effects of Venezuelan migration to Colombia: reconciling conflicting results. IZA J Dev Migr 13(1)

  • Lebow J (2024) Immigration and occupational downgrading in Colombia. J Dev Econ 166:103164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS, McCrary J, Moreira MJ, Porter J (2022) Valid t-ratio inference for IV. Am Econ Rev 112(10):3260–3290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichter A, Peichl A, Siegloch S (2015) The own-wage elasticity of labor demand: a meta-regression analysis. Eur Econ Rev 80:94–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López García I (2015) Human capital and labor informality in Chile: a life-cycle approach

  • Monras J (2020) Immigration and wage dynamics: evidence from the Mexican peso crisis. J Polit Econ 128(8):000–000

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morales-Zurita LF, Bonilla-Mejía L, Hermida D, Flórez LA, Bonilla-Mejía L, Morales LF, Hermida-Giraldo D, Flórez LA (2020) The labor market of immigrants and non-immigrants evidence from the Venezuelan refugee crisis. No, Borradores de Economía, p 1119

  • OECD (2023) Earnings: minimum wages relative to median wages

  • Olivieri S, Ortega F, Rivadeneira A, Carranza E (2021) Shoring up economic refugees: Venezuelan migrants in the Ecuadoran labor market. Migration Stud 9(4):1590–1625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penaloza-Pacheco L (2022) Living with the neighbors: the effect of Venezuelan forced migration on the labor market in Colombia. J Labour Market Res 56(1):1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pustejovsky JE, Tipton E (2018) Small-sample methods for cluster-robust variance estimation and hypothesis testing in fixed effects models. J Bus Econ Stat 36(4):672–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • RAMV (2018) Informe Final Registro Administrativo de Migrantes Venezolanos en Colombia. Technical report. Available on: https://www.refworld.org.es/pdfid/5b2957524.pdf (Last Accessed 28 Nov 2021)

  • Roodman D, Nielsen MØ, MacKinnon JG, Webb MD (2019) Fast and wild: bootstrap inference in Stata using boottest. Stand Genomic Sci 19(1):4–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Rozo SV, Vargas JF (2021) Brothers or invaders? How crisis-driven migrants shape voting behavior. J Dev Econ 150:102636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samaniego de la Parra B, Bujanda LF, et al. (2020) Increasing the cost of informal workers: evidence from Mexico. Technical report

  • Santamaria J (2020) “When a stranger shall sojourn with thee”: the impact of the Venezuelan exodus on Colombian labor markets

  • Solon G, Haider SJ, Wooldridge JM (2015) What are we weighting for? J Hum Res 50(2):301–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UCAB (2020) Encuesta Nacional de Condiciones de Vida. Technical report, Universidad Católica Andrés Bello. Available on: https://assets.website-files.com/5d14c6a5c4ad42a4e794d0f7/5f03875cac6fc11b6d67a8a5_Presentaci%C3%B3n%20%20ENCOVI%202019-Pobreza_compressed.pdf (Last Accessed 7 July 2020)

  • Ulyssea G (2018) Firms, informality, and development: theory and evidence from Brazil. Am Econ Rev 108(8):2015–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNHCR (2023) Venezuela situation. Technical report, Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees. Available on: https://www.unhcr.org/venezuela-emergency.html (Last Accessed 9th Jan 2023)

  • Weber S, Péclat M (2017) A simple command to calculate travel distance and travel time. Stand Genomic Sci 17(4):962–971

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to the editor, Shuaizhang Feng, and three anonymous referees for their insightful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to Jan Stuhler for all the detailed comments, useful arguments, in-depth suggestions, and close guidance; to Luigi Minale for further remarks and discussions; and to Juanjo Dolado for the extensive revision of the manuscript. I thank Jesús Fernández-Huertas, Jorge Pérez Pérez, Lorenzo Aldeco, and Sarah Schneider-Strawcynski for the helpful feedback. In general, I am indebted to all the comments from participants in the UC3M Applied Reading Group, the Junior Economics of Migration Seminar, the Seminario de Economía Aplicada BANREP-UIS-UNAB, the 10th European Meeting of the Urban Economics Association, the 17th IZA Annual Migration Meeting, the Seminar Series of Banxico, the 14th Migration and Development Conference, and the Seminar at ZEW. I am also grateful for all the support from the DANE staff, especially from Geovanni Portilla. This paper was previously circulated as “Dynamics of Local Wages and Employment: Evidence from the Venezuelan Immigration in Colombia.” Replication files are available upon request. All errors are my own.

Funding

The author gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the Ministry of Science and Innovation in Spain through research grant PDI2019-108144GB-I00.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lukas Delgado-Prieto.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Shuaizhang Feng.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 692 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Delgado-Prieto, L. Immigration, wages, and employment under informal labor markets. J Popul Econ 37, 55 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-024-01028-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-024-01028-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation