1 Introduction

In this paper, we aim to enhance the explanation for the fertility dynamics observed in high-income countries. Our motivation stems from the fact that there is no clear explanation within the same theoretical framework for the fertility decline during the demographic transition and the reversal of the fertility decline above a certain income threshold.

Although the demographic transition and the factors causing the fertility decline have been examined extensively, the fertility rebound is a relatively new phenomenon that has not been adequately analyzed and understood by researchers.Footnote 1 To this end, several recent studies corroborate that the decline in average fertility rates has reversed in high-income countries in recent decades.Footnote 2

A fertility rebound also occurs as a relative increase in fertility rates of high-income agents in the cross-section of the population (Hazan and Zoabi 2015). Such a cross-sectional rebound in fertility is represented by an inverse J-shaped curve. For example, Fig. 1 shows a curve of the nexus between the total fertility rate (TFR) and years of education based on US data. The figure shows that the relationship between fertility rates and years of education changed over time. In 1990 and 2000, the fertility rates declined with higher levels of education. However, in 2010 and 2018, fertility rates rebounded for high-income women. Another notable pattern is that the fertility rates in 2010 and 2018 are higher compared with those in 2000 at all education levels, thereby implying that the average fertility rates have risen in recent years. In addition, the fertility rates of high-income women with the same education levels in 2018 were higher than in 2010. Thus, based on the observations above, we can conclude that fertility rates rebound in the cross-section of the population and the shifts in the relationship between fertility and human capital levels increased the average fertility rates over time.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Data from the General Social Survey (GSS) by Norc at the University of Chicago, https://gssdataexplorer.norc.org/

Evolution of the fertility differentiation across education levels in the USA.

The rebound of the average fertility rates is illustrated in the following examples. Figure 2 shows that an inverse J-shaped relationship between the average TFR and the average human capital level is present for high-income countries in recent years. Similar patterns can be detected in the evolution of the country average cohort fertility rates (CFRs). Figure 3 shows the country average CFRs have a similar inverse J-shaped pattern over time (Fig. 3, panel d). The evolution of the nexus between CFRs and education levels is not homogeneous across education levels and countries. The cohort fertility rates of women with basic tertiary education (ISCED4-5B) increased after 1999 (Fig. 3, panels a and b). In 2014, the CFRs of women with post-secondary education (ISCED3-4) and tertiary education (ISCED5) were considerably higher compared with the CFRs in previous years.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Except in (d), the following countries are included: Austria, Australia, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, the UK, and the USA. The average years of education and fertility rates by country are used, except in (a). In (a), the average fertility rates are calculated for a group of countries with the same average education level in a given year. The curves are determined using the loess smoothing method. Source of data: World Development Indicators, World Bank, which includes the Barro and Lee dataset on education

Total fertility rates-education nexus in a sample of high-income countries, 1960–2010.

Fig. 3
figure 3

In (b) and (d), the following countries are included: Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, and the USA. In (a) and (c), the following countries are included: Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Spain, and Italy. The curves in (b) and (d) are determined using the loess smoothing method. Educational level is coded according to the International Standard Classification of Education 1997 (ISCED). ISCED0-2A stands for “no to lower-secondary education”; ISCED3-4 — “upper-secondary education to post-secondary non-tertiary education”; ISCED4-5B — “up to first stage of tertiary education”; ISCED5 — “tertiary education.” It is assumed that cohort fertility is completed when a woman is 44 years old. Source of data: (a), (b), and (c) Zeman et al. (2017); (d) Human Fertility Database (2021)

Cohort fertility-education nexus in a sample of high-income countries.

The reason for the inverse J-shaped pattern between economic development and fertility remains ambiguous from the theoretical perspective. First, the literature highlights that the steepness of the decline in fertility rates during the demographic transition and the shifts in the income–fertility relationship over time cannot be fully explained only by the trade-off between the quantity and quality of children caused by income growth and the related decline in infant and child mortality (Doepke 2005; Jones et al. 2010). This implies that the theoretical framework focusing on fertility choice lacks important factors that contribute to the observed fertility decline. Second, the literature does not provide a clear explanation for the factors causing a rebound in the average fertility rates.Footnote 3

Although Day (2016), Futagami and Konishi (2019), and Hirazawa and Yakita (2017), and Ohinata and Varvarigos (2019) achieved significant progress in analyzing the forces behind the recent fertility rebound, clear insights into some important aspects of this phenomenon are still missing. These studies on the fertility rebound identified that the decreasing relative costs of child-rearing (childcare and education costs) and longevity are preventing further decline or driving the fertility rates upward. However, these studies are based on models that lack some important features: Social externalities or human capital accumulation are not considered (Day 2016; Futagami and Konishi 2019); the fertility rebound cannot be explained if the opportunity cost of child-rearing is used instead of the direct cost (Ohinata and Varvarigos 2019); and the fertility rebound cannot be explained if the old generation is not allowed to work (Hirazawa and Yakita 2017). Finally, the literature does not provide a comprehensive explanation for the relationship between the fertility rebound observed in the cross-section of agents (Hazan and Zoabi 2015) and the dynamic rebound in the average fertility rates.

To address the issues above, we extend the standard fertility choice modelFootnote 4 by incorporating additional features. First, our model incorporates the following factors along with agents’ human capital: consumption and human capital externalities, the probability of child survival, social norms related to the number of children, relative childcare costs, and substitution of mothers’ child-rearing time with fathers’ time. Second, we capture the nexus between income and fertility in a more general form by modeling child-rearing costs using the opportunity cost of labor and the economic cost of education. Third, our approach generalizes the modeling of childcare time costs by incorporating market-based childcare services (Hazan and Zoabi 2015) and fathers’ involvement in child-rearing (Siegel 2017). Finally, we consider the effect of externalities on an agent’s consumption stemming from others’ consumption in society, which also affects fertility choice through the budget constraint.

The analysis based on the extended fertility choice model yields the following results. The steep decline in fertility rates during the demographic transition is caused by the quality-quantity trade-off, which is augmented by the fertility effects of social externalities and increases in child survival rates. Specifically, consumption externalities reduce the fertility rate by increasing the marginal value of consumption compared with that of having children. Moreover, the higher benchmark human capital negatively affects fertility by raising the survival and education of children and benchmark consumption. In addition, the declining benchmark fertility rate has a magnifying effect on the overall fertility choice dynamics. Therefore, the observed steepness of the decline in fertility during the demographic transition is also attributed to the changes in the benchmark fertility that reinforce the fall in fertility rates.

The paper also suggests an explanation for the recent rebound in fertility rates in high-income countries. This rebound is caused by the interplay of several factors. First, at significantly high benchmark levels of human capital and consumption, the marginal effect of these external factors on fertility diminishes. Therefore, further increases in benchmark levels of human capital and consumption do not have any additional negative effect on the fertility rate. Second, a decrease in child-rearing costs generated by market-based childcare services causes a fertility rebound among high-income agents. Given the increase in the benchmark fertility rates, externalities stemming from fertility norms push the average fertility rates up.Footnote 5 This positive effect of fertility externalities becomes relatively strong due to the presence of diminishing marginal effects of consumption and human capital externalities on fertility with income levels. As a combined outcome of these two effects, the average fertility rates increase.

This paper contributes to the literature by develo** a novel explanation for the fertility rebound in a more general setting than the ones considered in existing studies. For example, Hazan and Zoabi (2015) examine a cross-sectional fertility rebound; however, unlike our model, their model is not dynamic. In addition, we capture the discontinuous effect of heterogeneity among agents on childcare costs by making the childcare cost endogenous only for agents who have sufficiently high human capital and thus can afford market-based childcare services. Our paper also differs from papers that address the fertility rebound from a dynamic perspective. Unlike Futagami and Konishi (2019), Hirazawa and Yakita (2017), and Ohinata and Varvarigos (2019), by accounting for the heterogeneity of agents, our model captures social externalities stemming from differences among agents in consumption, human capital, and fertility. In our model, the rebound in the average fertility rates does not require a decrease in inequality, as in Day (2016). In contrast, we use inequality (heterogeneity) to generate social externalities in terms of consumption, human capital, and fertility norms. From this perspective, our model reconciles the rebound in the fertility of high-income agents relative to low-income agents and its dynamic implications for the average fertility rebound.

We test the findings of this study by simulating fertility rates using plausible parameter values calibrated to match the empirical moments from the distributions of human capital and completed cohort fertility rates for high-income countries. We use average completed cohort fertility rates as the appropriate statistic to represent the average fertility rate captured in our model, because the model determines the completed fertility rates of the adult agents in each generation.Footnote 6

The simulated average fertility rates exhibit an inverse J-shaped relationship between human capital and completed cohort fertility observed in high-income economies (Figs. 4 and 5). Specifically, the simulated fertility rates fall initially, emulating the demographic transition; then, at higher income levels, the fertility rates rebound and reach the level of average cohort rates observed in high-income economies over 1980–2020. The simulated model also generates an inverse J-shaped fertility-income relationship in the cross-section of heterogeneous agents with high average years of education (see below).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source of data: The TFRs are from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. The CFRs are from Human Fertility Database (2021). See Appendix A. The model is calibrated to target the CFR for 1985. The simulated total fertility rates (SCFRs) to 2105 are presented. The horizontal axis measures time in years, and the vertical axis measures the fertility rates. Each generation spans 25 years

Simulated and observed fertility rates in high-income countries, 1960–2085.

Fig. 5
figure 5

The parameter values are given in Appendix A

Simulated cross-section fertility–human capital relationship for distributions with different initial average human capital (education) \(\bar {h}_{1}\).

Therefore, our model captures the relationship between human capital inequality and fertility in the cross-section, which, in the presence of social externalities and endogenous childcare costs and child survival, provides a plausible explanation for the non-monotone evolution dynamics of fertility over long time horizons. In addition, we experiment with the calibrated model by shutting down effects stemming from social externalities. The results show that one cannot fully emulate the observed pattern of fertility evolution in high-income countries by omitting the social externalities and endogenous childcare costs from the model.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we describe the basic model with social externalities. In Section 3, we present an equilibrium analysis. In Section 4, we carry out a calibration analysis to establish whether the theoretical model can capture the documented evolution of the average fertility rates by exhibiting their initial decline during the demographic transition and the subsequent rebound at high-income levels. In Section 5, we conclude the paper.

2 Model

2.1 Household preferences

In our overlap**-generation model (OLG), we assume that agents live in two periods: childhood and adulthood. Adult agents are indexed by i and are endowed with one unit of time, which they supply inelastically in a competitive labor market and child-rearing. We also assume that the agents are heterogeneous in terms of their human capital levels. The probability distribution function (pdf) of human capital over the adult population is given by f(hit). Adult agents care about their consumption, cit ≥ 0, the number of children surviving to adulthood with the probability, πit, and their human capital, hit+ 1. This assumption implies that the number of children born and alive after infancy is given by πnit.

The probability of survival is defined similarly to Blackburn and Cipriani (2002) and is given as a function of the level of the parents’ human capital and other external factors:

$$ \pi(h_{it}, \bar{h}_{t})=\min\left( 1,\underline{\pi}\bar{h}_{t}^{{1-\sigma}} h_{it}^{{\sigma}}\right), $$
(1)

where \(0<\underline {\pi }<1\), σ < 1; thus, if π < 1,

$$\frac{\partial \pi_{it} }{\partial h_{it}}= \sigma\underline{\pi}\left( \frac{\bar{h}_{t}}{h_{it}}\right)^{1-\sigma}>0,$$

and

$$\frac{\partial^{2} \pi_{it} }{\partial h_{it}^{2}}=-(1-\sigma)\sigma\underline{\pi}{\bar{h}_{t}^{1-\sigma}}{h_{it}^{\sigma-2}}<0.$$

In our specification, we follow Strulik (2004) and assume that π is partly determined by parents’ decisions and partly by external factors. It is reasonable to assume that the latter part of survival probability depends on overall healthcare conditions that are driven by the average (benchmark) human capital level, \(\bar {h}_{t}\). However, this formulation of the probability of survival implies that for high human capital levels, it is possible that πit = 1. That is, a further increase in human capital does not affect survival of a child, as soon as π = 1.

In our model, fertility optimization is affected by externalities stemming from the average consumption, fertility, and human capital levels. Specifically, the agent obtains utility not only from their consumption and the effective number of children but also from the relative level of their consumption and fertility. Thus, the effective input of the consumption part in the utility function is determined as \(c^{1-\delta }_{it}\left (\frac {c_{it}}{\bar {c}_{t}}\right )^{\delta }\), where \(\bar {c}_{t}\) is the level of the benchmark (average) consumption. As the individual consumption level depends on the individual human capital level, it is reasonable to expect that the benchmark (average) consumption level, \(\bar {c}_{t}\), depends positively on the benchmark (average) human capital, \(\bar {h}_{t}\). Thus, this relationship can be expressed as \(\bar {c}_{t}=p\bar {h}_{t}\), where p < 1 is the marginal propensity to consume. Analogously, the effective input of the fertility part in the utility function is given as \(n^{1-\varepsilon }_{it}\left (\frac {n_{it}}{\bar {n}_{t}}\right )^{\varepsilon }\), where \(\bar {n}_{t}\) is the level of the benchmark (average or another reference level) fertility. In other words, the level of utility depends on agent’s consumption and fertility levels. In addition, the level of unity depends on the externalities stemming from the standing of the agents relative to the social benchmark.Footnote 7 We impose the restrictions δ < 1 and ε < 1 to ensure that the instantaneous utility is an increasing function of the absolute level of the household’s consumption and fertility.

Following de la Croix and Doepke (2003) and Fioroni (2010), and Omori (2009), the human capital level of a child hit+ 1 evolves according to

$$ h_{it+1}=B_{t}\left( \bar{h}_{t}^{\beta_{2}} h_{it}^{\beta_{1}}\right)^{1-\theta}e^{\theta}_{it}, $$
(2)

where eit is parents’ education spending, hit is the level of the parents’ human capital, and \(\bar {h}_{t}\) is the benchmark human capital level, which captures the positive effect of externalities on human capital accumulation. To rule out the implausible case of human capital accumulation of an individual decreasing in human capital externalities and in parents’ human capital, we assume 0 < 𝜃 < 1, 0 < β1 < 1 and β1 + β2 ≤ 1. These restrictions allow the education function to be in line with the empirical evidence.Footnote 8 The last restriction is used to accommodate the possibility of decreasing returns to scale in terms of the contribution of human capital (parental and external) to the human capital accumulation of the next generation. The productivity coefficient of the education function is given by Bt > 0. This coefficient is useful for scaling the results in a numerical simulation of the model. We assume that this coefficient increases along with the average human capital and is expressed as \(B_{t}=B_{0} \bar {h}_{t}^{\xi }\), where B0 is the initial value of the coefficient, and ξ is the parameter capturing the effect of average human capital \(\bar {h}_{t}\) on the overall productivity of the education system.

In light of the discussion above, the utility function of an agent incorporates social externalities along with the standard choice variables, such as consumption, education spending, and the number of children.Footnote 9 We state the utility function of an agent in the following constant elasticity of substitution (CES) form:

$$ U_{it}=\gamma\left[\alpha(\bar{c}^{-\delta}_{t} c_{it})^{\rho}+(1-\alpha)\left( \bar{n}_{t}^{-\varepsilon}n_{it}B_{t}\left( \bar{h}_{t}^{\beta_{2}} h_{it}^{\beta_{1}}\right)^{1-\theta} \pi e_{it}^{\theta}\right)^{\rho}\right]^{\frac{1}{\rho}}. $$
(3)

Note that the expressions above for consumption and fertility inputs in the utility function are simplified to \(c_{it}\bar {c}_{t}^{-\delta }\) and \(n_{it}\bar {n}_{t}^{-\varepsilon }\) as they are given in (3).

2.2 Household budget constraint

Agents generate income by working for firms. We assume a simple production function specified as follows:

$$ y_{it}=wh_{it}l_{it}, $$
(4)

where w is the wage rate, and lit is the amount of labor supplied (time spent working). Normalizing the time available to unity, we impose the following restriction on the labor supply:

$$0< l_{it}\leq1.$$

Given that income is a linear function of effective labor, for simplicity, we normalize the wage rate, w, to 1. This form of production modeling is standard for fertility choice models.

Having a child is costly in terms of the time spent on child-rearing. In modeling the child-rearing costs, we adopt a more general approach by allowing for direct costs (Hazan and Zoabi 2006; Ohinata and Varvarigos 2019) and opportunity costs (e.g. de la Croix and Doepke 2003). That is, the cost of child-rearing includes the time cost and the monetary cost of education. As the length of childhood is determined by nature, we can assume that rearing each child requires time that is equal to τ.

Following Day (2016) and Hazan and Zoabi (2015), we assume that parents look after their children some of the time and can hire childcare services for the rest of the time. We build this rationale from the fact that without childcare services, the cost of childcare is captured by the time parents spend looking after their children. By definition, this means that the total time spent raising a child is fixed and comprises time parents spent raising their children and time children spent at hired childcare. We assume that the average human capital level of childcare service workers is given by \(\underline {h}_{t}\in (0,\bar {h}_{t})\). To abstract from the problem of modeling the childcare labor market, we assume this value is determined exogenously as a function of the average human capital.Footnote 10 Therefore, we write the human capital level in the childcare sector as \(\underline {h}_{t}=\chi \bar {h}{}^{\nu }\), where 0 < ν < 1, and χ > 0.

We integrate childcare services by assuming that the cost of child-rearing for an agent is given by ψitτht. Here, τ is the exogenous time cost of raising a child, whereas the childcare cost function is given as follows:

$$ \psi_{it} =\left\{\begin{array}{l} {1, \text{if} \frac{h_{it}}{ \underline{h}_{t}}\leq 1 }, \\ {\chi\frac{\underline{h}_{t}}{h_{it}^{\nu}}, 0 <\psi_{it}<1,\text{if} \frac{h_{it}}{ \underline{h}_{t}}>1}. \end{array}\right. $$
(5)

That is, only if the level of human capital is greater than the human capital level given in the childcare sector (\(\underline {h}_{t} \)) does a person use childcare services; otherwise, a person uses only their own time. The exact form of the childcare functions is given as

$$\psi_{it}=\chi\frac{\underline{h}_{t}}{h_{it}^{\nu}}.$$

The assumed functional form of ψit implies that use of childcare services is increasing in the parent’s human capital level. Therefore, the higher the parents’ education level, the less of their own time parents use for childcare. Thus,

$$\frac{\partial \psi_{it}}{\partial h_{it}}=-\chi \nu\frac{\underline{h}_{t}}{h^{(\nu+1)}_{it}}<0.$$

In addition, the marginal effect of the parent’s human capital is decreasing in the level of her human capital at an increasing rate. Thus,

$$\frac{\partial^{2} \psi_{it}}{\partial h_{it}^{2}}={(1+\nu)}\nu\chi \frac{\underline{h}_{t}}{h^{(\nu+2)}_{it}}>0.$$

This assumption is in line with the plausible condition that parents still spend some minimum time raising their children even when they can afford to hire childcare services for the whole time.

This modeling approach also allows us to incorporate the argument by Siegel (2017), who demonstrates that as women’s earning capacity rises, housework substitution from husbands to wives decreases the time cost for women; and thus, it decreases the cost of having children. This type of time-cost substitution increases fertility. Therefore, the parameter ν captures not only the effect of market-based childcare services but also the substitution of husbands’ time spent on childcare. For agents with high enough human capital so that ψit < 1, a further increase in their human capital should decrease the use of their own time in child-rearing; the magnitude of this change also depends on the value of ν. Another point to note is that to avoid modeling the childcare sector explicitly, and to keep the model simple, we assume that ψit captures the effective decrease in the opportunity cost of child-rearing net of the cost of childcare services. For example, if an agent decreases the time cost on a child by 30%, but say one-third of that additional time is spent on generating income to cover the cost of childcare services, then the effective value of ψit is only 0.8, not 0.7. Thus, we assume that parameter χ > 1.

Because any decrease in ψit implies that the direct time cost of a parent decreases, which increases the fertility rate of the affected agent (as in Day 2016; Hazan and Zoabi 2015; Siegel 2017), taking this structure in childcare, the effective labor supply is expressed as

$$ l_{it}=(1-\psi_{it} \tau). $$
(6)

Accounting for the labor supply and the cost of child-rearing, the budget constraint faced by an agent is stated as

$$ c_{it}=h_{it}[1-(\tau \psi_{it} +e_{it})n_{it}], $$
(7)

where eit is the amount of income spent on education for each child, and τ is the time required to raise a child.

2.3 The role of social externalities in fertility choice

In the formulation of the utility function given above, we incorporated several social externalities. In this section, we discuss the motivation for adding these externalities and highlight why these externalities are essential in agents’ utility maximization.

The critical reason for incorporating consumption externalities into agents’ utility function is based on the following intuition: The literature highlighted that consumption externalities have a significant effect on the inter-temporal allocation of individual consumption. Thus, agents jointly consider capital accumulation, fertility, savings, labor supply, and consumption in their choice decision-making process. Therefore, adult agents’ marginal utility from consumption depends on social preference levels for consumption measured by the benchmark consumption level, \(\bar {c}_{t}\) (Cigno and Rosati 1996; Chen et al. 2015; Park 2018).Footnote 11

The literature on fertility choice (Barro and Becker 1989; de la Croix and Doepke 2004; Doepke 2005) assumes that agents care about the quality and number of their children, expressed as the following product: nithi,t+ 1. Both variables are subject to external effects. For example, Bhattacharya and Chakraborty (2012), Dasgupta (2000), Goto (2008), and Munshi and Myaux (2006), and Palivos (2001) link the fertility evolution to social norms related to the number of children families choose to have. The finding that the fertility rebound income level depends on the fertility rate at the start of the demographic transition (Lacalle-Calderon et al. 2017) also highlights the existence of fertility externalities. Based on a rationale similar to the case of consumption externalities, we assume that the average number of children per parent, \(\bar {n}\), exerts an additional effect on the utility of an agent gained from having a certain number of children.Footnote 12

Several studies demonstrate that average human capital and income levels in society (Hazan and Zoabi 2006; Kalemli-Ozcan 2002; Strulik 2004) generate externalities that improve a child’s health and consequently, increase the relative return to the quality of a child. By driving economic conditions, these externalities affect investment levels in children’s education and thus impact the quality-quantity trade-off in fertility choice. Moreover, the average human capital level in a society provides an external effect on fertility rates through the impact on education costs (de la Croix and Doepke 2003). Formally, de la Croix and Doepke (2003) argue that the evolution process of human capital depends not only on educational spending, eit, and the level of parents’ human capital, hit, but also on the (average) benchmark human capital level, \(\bar {h}_{t}\), which exerts positive externalities on human capital accumulation.

In Section 3, we demonstrate how the interplay of these social externalities and changes in child-rearing costs drives an inverse J-shaped relationship between fertility and economic development. Moreover, a sensitivity analysis of the calibrated model in which these externalities mechanisms are shut down that only by accounting for these externalities can we emulate the observed average fertility dynamics in high-income countries.

2.4 Aggregate variables

Given that we are dealing with heterogeneous agents, we consider how some of the variables are aggregated. The average human capital level, \({\bar {h}}_{t}\), is given as

$$ {{\bar{h}}_{t}}={\int}_{h_{min}}^{h_{max}}{{{h}_{it}}}f({{h}_{it}})d{{h}_{it}}. $$
(8)

The total population evolves as the product of the weighted average fertility rate and the population in the current period:

$$ P_{t+1}=P_{t}{\int}_{h_{min}}^{h_{max}} n_{it}\pi_{it} f_{t}(h_{it})dh_{it}. $$
(9)

The average fertility rate is determined by

$$ \bar{n}_{t}={\int}_{h_{min}}^{h_{max}} n_{it} f_{t}(h_{it})dh_{it}, $$
(10)

whereas the average consumption level is determined by

$$ \bar{c}_{t}={\int}_{h_{min}}^{h_{max}} c_{it} f_{t}(h_{it})dh_{it}. $$
(11)

The distribution of human capital evolves as followsFootnote 13:

$$ f_{t}({{h}_{it}})=\left[ \frac{{{P}_{0}}}{{{P}_{t}}}\prod\limits_{\tau =0}^{t}{{{n}_{i\tau }}} \right]{{f }_{0}}({{h}_{i0}}). $$
(12)

2.5 The agent’s problem

In the setting specified above, the agent’s problem is given by:

$$ \mathop{\max }\limits_{c,n, e} U= \gamma\left[\alpha (\bar{c}^{-\delta}_{t} c_{it})^{\rho}+(1-\alpha)\left( B_{t}\bar{n}_{t}^{-\varepsilon}\left( \bar{h}_{t}^{\beta_{2}} h_{it}^{\beta_{1}}\right)^{1-\theta}e^{\theta}_{it}\pi_{t} n_{it}\right)^{\rho}\right]^{\frac{1}{\rho}}, $$
(13)
$$ s.t. c_{it}=h_{it}[1-(\psi_{it}\tau+e_{it} ) n_{it}]. $$
(14)

In the problem statement, we dropped the non-negativity constraints imposed on cit and hit, because they are non-binding for this class of problems.

The agent’s problem can be solved by maximizing the following Lagrangian:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} L=\gamma\left[\alpha (\bar{c}^{-\delta}_{t} c_{it})^{\rho}+(1-\alpha)\left( B_{t}\bar{n}_{t}^{-\varepsilon}\left( \bar{h}_{t}^{\beta_{2}} h_{it}^{\beta_{1}}\right)^{1-\theta}e^{\theta}_{it}(\pi_{it} n_{it})\right)^{\rho}\right]^{\frac{1}{\rho}}\\ +\lambda [h_{it}[1-(\psi_{it}\tau+e_{it} ) n_{it}]-c_{it}]. \end{array} $$
(15)

Solving for the optimal values of eit and nit, we obtain (see Appendix A for details):

$$ e_{it}^{*}=\frac{\theta h_{it}\tau\psi_{it}}{1-\theta}, $$
(16)
$$ n_{it}^{*}=\frac{h_{it}\left( \frac{ h_{it}\tau\psi_{it}}{1-\theta} \alpha \right)^{{\frac{1}{\rho-1}}}}{\left[(1-\alpha)\left( B_{t}\bar{n}_{t}^{-\varepsilon}\left( \bar{h}_{t}^{\beta_{2}} h_{it}^{\beta_{1}}\right)^{1-\theta}\pi_{it}\left( \frac{\theta h_{it}\tau\psi_{it}}{1-\theta}\right)^{\theta}\right)^{\rho}\right]^{{\frac{1}{\rho-1}}}{\bar{c}_{t}^{\frac{\delta\rho}{\rho-1}}}+\left[\left( \frac{ h_{it}\tau\psi_{it}}{1-\theta} \right)^{\rho}\alpha \right]^{{\frac{1}{\rho-1}}}} $$
(17)

The equilibrium consumption level is determined using the budget constraint (14).

2.6 Definition of equilibrium

Given an initial distribution of human capital f0(h0), an initial population size P0, and the human capital level in the childcare sector \(\underline {h}_{t}\), an equilibrium consists of sequences of aggregate quantities \(\{ \bar {c}_{t}, \bar {h}_{t}, \bar {n}_{t}, P_{t +1}\}\), distributions ft(hit), and decision rules for consumption, fertility, education spending, and human capital accumulation \(\left \{c_{it}, n_{it}, e_{it}, h_{it+1}, \right \}\) such that:

  • the individual’s decision rules {cit,nit,eit,hit+ 1} maximize the utility function, subject to constraints (14) and (2) and the evolution of child survival (1) and childcare costs (5);

  • markets clear by labor being distributed between childcare of own children and production (6), and in the goods market, the output is allocated among consumption, education spending, and childcare services (7);

  • aggregate variables \(\bar {h}_{t}\), Pt, \(\bar {n}_{t}\), and \(\bar {c}_{t}\) are given by (8), (9), (10), and (11), respectively; and

  • the distribution of human capital evolves according to (12).

The concavity of the utility function and a linear production function ensures the existence of equilibrium.

3 Equilibrium analysis

3.1 The effect of externalities stemming from others’ consumption

We state the following proposition by analyzing the expression for the equilibrium fertility rate (17).

Proposition 3.1

Consumption externalities exhibit a negative effect on fertility rates. The marginal effect of consumption externalities on fertility diminishes with the increase in the benchmark consumption.

Proof

Using (17), it can be verified that \( \frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial \bar {c}_{t}}<0\). In addition, it can be shown that \(\lim _{\bar {c}_{t} \to \infty }\frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial \bar {c}_{t}}\rightarrow 0\). Thus, with a rise in benchmark consumption, the marginal effect of consumption externalities on fertility diminishes. See Appendix A for details.□

When the benchmark consumption levels increase due to positive externalities, this change lifts the marginal utility of consumption. Given the budget constraint, agents respond to this change by increasing their consumption levels and decreasing their fertility rate. In the earlier stages of the demographic transition, the benchmark consumption levels are relatively low; thus, consumption externalities exert an additional downward push on fertility. This additional pressure on fertility rates stemming from consumption externalities contributes to the observed steep decline in fertility rates. However, there is a limit to this effect stemming from consumption, because the marginal effect of consumption externalities on fertility tends to zero at significantly high levels of benchmark consumption. In other words, after reaching some high threshold values, a further increase in the benchmark consumption levels will not have any further significant effect on agents’ fertility.

3.2 The effect of externalities stemming from others’ human capital

In this setting, the comparative statics analysis of nit with regard to \( \bar {h}_{t}\) yields the following proposition:

Proposition 3.2

Human capital externalities exhibit a negative effect on fertility rates. The marginal effect of human capital externalities on fertility diminishes with the increase in the benchmark human capital levels.

Proof

Using (17), it can be verified that \( \frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial \bar {h}_{t}}<0\). It can also be shown that with an increase in \(\bar {h}_{t}\), the marginal effect of human capital externalities on fertility diminishes. That is, we can show that

$$\lim_{\bar{h}_{t} \to \infty} \frac{\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial \bar{h}_{t}}= 0.$$

See Appendix A for details. □

This result indicates that when the level of benchmark human capital is above a certain threshold, the fertility rate does not depend on a further increase in the benchmark human capital. In other words, after a certain threshold level is reached, a further increase in levels of benchmark human capital will not have any significant effect on agents’ fertility.

3.3 The effect of externalities stemming from others’ fertility

By analyzing the equilibrium fertility rate given by (17), we can state the following proposition:

Proposition 3.3

In the presence of social externalities stemming from fertility norms (when ε > 0), an increase in the benchmark level of fertility, \(\bar {n}\), raises the fertility rate of an agent.

Proof

Using (17), it can be verified that \(\frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial \bar {n}_{t}}>0\). See Appendix A for details. □

This result indicates that the existence of externalities stemming from the socially desirable level of fertility makes the effect of consumption and human capital externalities even stronger in the early stages of the demographic transition. This outcome occurs because increases in the benchmark levels of consumption and human capital reduce the benchmark fertility rate, which creates additional externalities and exerts additional downward pressure on individual fertility choice. The complementarity of these externalities explains why the fertility rates spiral rapidly downward during the demographic transition. However, when the positive effect of the externalities stemming from fertility norms dominates the effects of other social externalities on fertility choice, the condition explains the recent reversal of the fertility decline in high-income countries. We discuss this aspect in more detail in Section 3.5.

3.4 The role of human capital in the quantity and quality of children

In this section, we demonstrate that the effect of individual human capital on education spending and fertility rates can be different depending on whether an agent’s human capital is above a certain threshold. First, we state the following lemma by analyzing the equilibrium value of education spending given by (16).

Lemma 3.4

Spending on education increases with parents’ human capital level. This effect is greater for those who do not use market-based childcare services than for those who use these services.

Proof

\(e_{it}^{*}=\frac {\theta h_{it}\tau \psi _{it}}{1-\theta }.\) Taking the first-order derivative of (16) yields for the case with market-based childcare services:

$$\frac{\partial e_{it}}{\partial h_{it}}=\frac{\psi_{it}\theta\tau }{(1-\theta)}>0.$$

If the agent does not use market-based childcare services, then we have ψit = 1. Thus, we have

$$\frac{\partial e_{it}}{\partial h_{it}}=\frac{\theta\tau }{(1-\theta)}>0.$$

Given that for the case with market-based childcare services ψit < 1, it can be verified that the marginal effect of parents’ human capital level on education spending is greater for those who cannot afford market-based childcare services than for those who can. □

The positive effect of human capital is in line with the evidence for the relationship between parents’ human capital level and spending on children’s education (Hazan and Zoabi 2015). Moreover, our result provides a theoretical perspective on the increasing relative cost of private education observed in developed economies.Footnote 14 In particular, we show that agents with lower human capital endowment respond more strongly to the increase in their human capital by investing more in the education of their children.

Next, we analyze the effect of individual human capital on the fertility rate given by (17) and state the following proposition.

Proposition 3.5

The effect of an increase in parents’ human capital level on the fertility rate depends on whether the human capital level is below or above a certain threshold value, \(\tilde {h}_{t}\). It can be shown that the following conditions hold:

$$ \frac{\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial h_{it}} \left\{\begin{array}{l} {<0, \text{if } h_{it}<\tilde{h}_{t}},\\{=0, \text{if } h_{it}=\tilde{h}_{t}},\\{>0, \text{if } h_{it}>\tilde{h}_{t}}. \end{array}\right. $$
(18)

Proof

It can be verified by considering the comparative statics of (17) that \(\frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial h_{it}}\gtrless 0 \). See Appendix A for details. □

As the equation \(\frac {\partial n_{it}^{*}}{\partial h_{it}}=0\), stemming from (18), is based on a nonlinear function of hit, we cannot solve it explicitly for the threshold value of \(\tilde {h}_{t}\). However, we solve the equation numerically for given parameter values in the calibration section of the paper. This result shows that our model captures the inverse J-shaped income–fertility relationship at the individual level as demonstrated by Futagami and Konishi (2019), Hazan and Zoabi (2015), and Ohinata and Varvarigos (2019), and Siegel (2017). However, we show that this rebound is not determined purely by the income effect as the authors above found; instead, the rebound occurs when the income effect dominates the child survival effect (the details are in Appendix A.35). The main point is that only agents with sufficiently high human capital can afford fertility rates increasing with the level of their human capital. In addition, the structural changes that reduce child-rearing costs (captured as a decrease in childcare cost function ψ) magnify the positive income effect on fertility. Only when agents with a positive income–fertility relationship stochastically dominate in the population, can we have a fertility rebound in the spirit of Day (2016). One can argue that with higher inequality levels, only a small fraction of the population experiences increasing fertility, the effect of which on average fertility would be more than offset by the decline in the fertility of the rest of the population. Given that inequality levels have been increasing in most of the advanced economies (Hoeller et al. 2013), it is not likely that this inequality effect on fertility rates is driving the overall fertility rebound. Thus, the effect of increasing human capital on overall fertility rates is not straightforward.

3.5 A reversal of the decline in fertility rates

Based on the findings of Hazan and Zoabi (2015) and Day (2016), and Siegel (2017), we infer that when the fall in the value of ψ is due to social and economic structural changes, the fertility of the part of the population affected by these changes would increase. The same outcome is also established in our model; that is, it can be verified that

$$\frac{\partial n_{it}}{\partial \psi_{it}}\frac{\partial \psi_{it}}{\partial {h}_{it}} >0.$$

Intuitively, such changes can lead to an increase in the benchmark fertility rates. Access to childcare services and the social change that leads to greater involvement of fathers in child-rearing can affect mostly the part of the population with high human capital levels. As women with high human and income levels naturally have higher social status, their fertility choices are more likely to influence social norms. If this hypothesis is true, then the increase in the fertility rates of women of this type can affect the social benchmark fertility (social norms). Thus, increases in the fertility of high-income women due to structural changes in childcare lead to an overall rise in fertility through fertility norm externalities.

The positive effect of fertility externalities would become noticeable only if this effect dominates other negative effects on fertility stemming from consumption and human capital externalities. Such an outcome is possible, as according to Proposition 3.1 and Proposition 3.2, at high benchmark levels of consumption and human capital, their marginal effect on fertility choice becomes negligible; thus, the effect of fertility externalities becomes dominant at high income levels. In light of this, we conclude that the combined effect of structural changes in child-rearing costs and social externalities on fertility choice is the main factor that explains the recent fertility rebound in high-income countries.

4 Calibration of the model and simulation results

In this section, we carry out a calibration analysis to establish whether our theoretical model can numerically replicate the documented evolution of average fertility rates and the rebound in fertility rates of high-income agents in a cross-section. High-income countries exhibit not only the demographic transition but have also experienced a rebound or stabilization in fertility rates. Therefore, it would be logical to test our model on data for high-income countries. That is, we verify whether the model can exhibit a steep decline in fertility rates at the low income levels (captured by the average human capital levels) and a rebound in fertility after a certain income threshold is reached.

To calibrate the fertility rate given by (17), we adopt the parameter values with some adjustment for the time cost per child, τ, the impact of the level of parents’ human capital on the level of children’s human capital, β1, the degree of altruism, α, and the elasticity of substitution, s, from similar calibrations presented in the literature discussed below. We determine the values of the other parameters by calibrating them to target the initial average fertility values for the selected high-income countries. As the theoretical model operates with generations as time periods, we set a year value for the period in the model. We follow Deopke (2004) and set the length of a generation to 25 years.

The social externalities incorporated in the model require heterogeneity of agents in terms of their human capital levels. Thus, we approximate the initial distribution of human capital. Because income is distributed according to the log-normal distribution (Young 2011), and given that human capital and income have a linear relationship (in our model), we also adopt a log-normal distribution for human capital. For the initial mean of the distribution, we adopt a log of 6.74 years of female education which is found to be the average years of education in 1960 for selected high-income countries using World Bank data. To determine the standard deviation of the log-normal distribution of human capital, we follow Aitchison and Brown (1957) and Young (2011). Aitchison and Brown (1957) show that for log-normally distributed population income, the Gini coefficient is given by \(G = 2N[{\varsigma }/\sqrt {2}]-1\), where ς is the standard deviation of the log of income. From The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER), the World Income Inequality Database (WIID), we obtain data for the Gini index and compute the standard deviation of the log of human capital as \({\varsigma }_{h}=\sqrt {2}N^{-1}[(G+1)/2]\).Footnote 15 The data on the Gini index is obtained. For the starting point in our calibration, we assume that G = 0.345. We approximate this value based on the average value of the Gini index for Germany and the in 1960, and for Denmark in 1961 as only for these countries Gini values were available.

The parameter values for the calibrated model are summarized in Table 1. We use the time cost per child, τ = 0.075, which is borrowed from de la Croix and Doepke (2004). Importantly, de la Croix and Doepke (2004) emphasize that the elasticity 𝜃 of human capital with respect to education should not be set too high; otherwise, the fertility differentials will be inflated. In our case, we aim to keep the initial average human capital accumulation above the average level of human capital of the first-generation parents. Thus, the elasticity of human capital with respect to education is set at 𝜃 = 0.115 (de la Croix and Doepke (2004) used 𝜃 = 0.16). In the same manner, we set the parameter that captures the impact of the level of parents’ human capital on the level of children’s human capital, β1 = 0.595. Similarly, the elasticity of children’s human capital with respect to the average human capital of the parent generation is set to allow for decreasing returns to scale for the human capital accumulation process. Thus, we set β2 = 0.21.

Table 1 Parameter values used in the calibration

The value of the altruism parameter is selected as α = 0.97, which is not far from the range of α ∈ [0.90–0.95] used in Córdoba et al. (2016). The value of ρ is calculated as \(\rho =\frac {s}{s-1}\), where s is the parameter of the elasticity of substitution. We use s = 1.5, as in Córdoba and Ripoll (2019), and set ρ = 3.Footnote 16

The average fertility rate captured in our model is the average of the completed fertility rates of the modeled adult agents in the current generation. Thus, the average completed cohort fertility rates observed in high-income countries are a more appropriate statistic for our model than the TFR.Footnote 17 We also note that the TFR is a measure of period fertility and is based on the decisions of many different cohorts at a given point in time. Thus, the TFR may suffer from tempo effects and does not seem to reflect the fertility statistic implied by our model.Footnote 18 Based on this logic, we set the following parameters to target the observed average cohort fertility rate in high-income economies, which was approximately equal to 2.24 in 1985.

We set the parameter values of consumption externalities, δ = 0.018, and fertility norms externalities, ε = 0.53. The parameters capturing the childcare cost reduction through market services and husbands’ involvement are set as follows: χ = 1.035 and ν = 0.65. This reduction in the time cost is applicable only to those who have a level of human capital exceeding the level of human capital in the childcare sector. The initial fertility norm \(\bar {n}_{1}\) is assumed to be equal to 3.9 children, and the initial average consumption is assumed to be given by \(\bar {c}_{1}=0.6\bar {h}_{1}\).

In setting the values for the productivity coefficient of the human capital accumulation function B0, we use the following rationale. Specifically, we tried to match the initial fertility rate and the human capital accumulation. We set B0 = 2.98 to match the initial \(\bar {h}_{t+1}\) and nt. The parameter capturing the effect of the marginal total productivity of the education system on the average level of human capital is set, ζ = − 0.002. Thus, the marginal total productivity of the education system is decreasing in the average level of human capital. Given that with a greater and more complex knowledge stock, it is logical to expect that human capital accumulation would require greater marginal costs. The probability of child survival \(\bar {\pi }\) and the elasticities of human capital (σ of the parent’s human capital, 1 − σ, of the average human capital) are calibrated to match the observed survival rates.Footnote 19 We start with a high average probability value of 0.95–0.97 as we are targeting the child survival rates in high-income countries from the 1960s and aim to get π = 1 in the second-to-third periods.

The time series plots for the simulated and observed fertility data are displayed in Fig. 4 and the dataset is given in Table 2. We parametrize the model by matching the simulated initial fertility rate with the observed initial cohort fertilit rate as discussed.

Table 2 Simulated and observed fertility rates in high-income countries

The comparison of the simulated fertility rates with the statistical data demonstrates that our model, for a feasible set of parameters, can simulate fertility rate dynamics that are consistent with the evolution of the observed CFRs. However, we admit that even with all the externalities incorporated and a quite ad hoc entry of market-based childcare services, we were not able to fully replicate the sharp decline in fertility rates observed in the data without having a rebound fertility rate that is lower than in the data. Thus, the simulated series shown in Fig. 4 closely matches the starting and rebound points in the data, but not the point at the end of the fertility decline. This implies that there are still some other factors that affect fertility choice that are not accounted for in the model.

The simulation results indicate that the model is not well suited for explaining the evolution of the TFRs. Although the simulated series show a pattern similar to that of the TFR, the model cannot produce the sharp decline manifested by the TFR. This deviation most likely stems from the tempo effects in the TFR, which are not captured in our simple OLG model.

The reasonable consistency of the actual CFR data with the computed fertility rates using the simulated model allows us to conclude that the model with social externalities adequately describes the evolution of completed fertility. In addition, the model captures the rebound (stabilization) of fertility rates in the long run. It appears that the demographic transition ends as soon as the countries reach certain development levels; after that, fertility rates gradually rebound (stabilize) as the income levels increase.

As shown in Fig. 5, we also evaluate whether the model can generate an inverse J-shaped fertility-income relationship in the cross-section of agents with different human capital levels. In particular, we tried to replicate the curves for 1990 and 2010 given in Fig. 1. The model yields fertility rates that decline with the education levels, when we use a distribution of human capital with an average of nine years of education. The simulated curve is similar to the curve of the relationship between education and fertility in 1990 observed in the USA. When we use a distribution of human capital with an average of 12 years of education, we obtain an inverse J-shaped fertility–human capital relationship as the curve for 2010 in the USA. Therefore, the model captures the possibility of rising fertility of the high-income agents observed in the USA (see Fig. 1). Intuitively, the cross-section simulation can also be used to explain the differences among countries in terms of their fertility. Such simulation shows, the differences among countries in terms of average human capital levels and their distribution across agents, as well as social externalities and childcare costs, contribute to agents’ fertility levels; these factors contribute to the changes in average fertility rates.

As a related issue, using (A15), we also find a numerical solution for \(\tilde {h}\). That is, we determine the threshold value for human capital that divides agents into two groups: (1) agents whose fertility declines when their human capital increases and (2) agents whose fertility rises when their human capital increases. For the same parameter values used in high-income countries, we find that the threshold education is equal to 14.1 years; that is, agents with more than 14.1 years of education can have an increase in fertility rates when their human capital increases further.

4.1 Sensitivity analysis

We conduct a sensitivity analysis to evaluate the role of the externalities and other new mechanisms incorporated into the model. We run the analyses by shutting off these channels one at a time and running the simulations of the model using the given set of parameters in Table 1 for the dynamic case and the values given in Appendix A for the cross-section case. We test the sensitivity of the model to the exclusion of a given factor by assuming ψ = 1 and π = 1 or assuming the corresponding elasticity of the factor is equal to zero as 𝜖 = 0, and δ = 0. We illustrate the restricted simulations against the benchmark simulations based on the model by including all the factors (see Fig. 6).

Fig. 6
figure 6

The sensitivity analyses: the benchmark vs. restricted cases

Shutting off the channel of the childcare (ψ = 1) makes the evolution of fertility rates smoother (see Fig. 6, panels a and b). With this simplification of the model, the simulated decline in fertility rates is lower, and the rebound is also less pronounced than otherwise.Footnote 20 The cross-sectional simulations highlight this effect: In the absence of market-based childcare services, fertility rates of higher-income agents increase more slowly than they would have in its presence. Thus, ignoring childcare costs would lead to underestimation of the rebound at the aggregate level, although for the parametrization we used, its impact appears weak.

The probability of survival (i.e., assuming π = 1) was not a significant factor for the overall dynamics of the model (see Fig. 6, panels c and d). It is reasonable, as high-income countries had high child survival rates in the last few decades. The probability of survival has some effect only in earlier periods, when the survival rate was below unity for low-income agents. We confirm this point with the simulations based on a cross-section of agents. These simulations show that the probability of survival is a crucial factor as long as it is not equal to unity for all the agents. For a small proportion of agents with a significant rate of child mortality, the curve of the fertility–income relationship becomes different when the effect of survival is ignored.

Analysis of the empirical role of social externalities in fertility rates provides the following findings. In particular, the consumption externalities explain some of the sharp decrease in the fertility rates at the beginning of the period we considered (see Fig. 6, panel e and f ). When we shut down this channel, by setting δ = 0, the simulated cross-sectional fertility rates are higher for all human capital levels. In the dynamic case, we cannot replicate the initial decline in the data. We obtain a significantly shallower simulated decline. In addition, without the consumption externalities effect, the rebound in fertility rates becomes higher, which results in a sharper increase in fertility rates than observed in the data. As expected, shutting down the effect of fertility externalities, by setting 𝜖 = 1, results in much lower fertility rates than the observed values (see Fig. 6, panels g and h). It appears that fertility norms play a significant role in the evolution of the overall fertility rates. In sum, the experiments confirm the structure of the theoretical model. We demonstrate that all three externalities are critical in the evolution of fertility choice over time. Thus, it seems necessary to account for these externalities in explaining agents’ fertility.

5 Conclusion

This paper develops an explanation for the so-called inverse J-shaped relationship between fertility and per capita income levels. We extend the standard fertility choice model by simultaneously accounting for endogenous childcare costs, child survival, and social externalities stemming from fertility norms, average human capital, and consumption. Using the extended fertility choice model, we find that at lower benchmark levels of human capital and consumption, their external effect on fertility is negative and significant. The effect of an increase in child survival rates is also negative. All these effects on fertility complement the “quality-quantity trade-off” effect and result in the steep fall in fertility rates during the demographic transition. In addition, the falling benchmark fertility rates, through fertility externalities, magnify the decrease in the average fertility rates. On the other hand, at high benchmark levels, the marginal external effects of human capital and consumption on fertility become negligible. Under such circumstances, the income effect and social and structural changes in childcare lead to growth in benchmark fertility rates. The increase in benchmark fertility rates raises average fertility rates through fertility norm externalities. This outcome explains the observed reversal of the decline in fertility rates in high-income countries in recent years.

The simulations based on the calibrated theoretical model demonstrate that the model emulates the observed evolution of the average cohort fertility rates for high-income economies. Specifically, the model dynamically simulates an initial decline in fertility, which then changes into a reversal (or stabilization) after a certain income threshold is reached. Furthermore, as social externalities, childcare, and child survival differentiation stem from the heterogeneity of agents, we conduct cross-sectional simulations of the model. We find that the model repproduce the inverse J-shaped fertility–income relationship in the cross-section of agents with different human capital levels observed in high-income countries. In addition, we conduct a sensitivity analysis by separately shutting off the externalities, childcare, and child survival channels in the model and running the simulations using the calibrated parameters. The results show that all three externalities (fertility norms, average human capital, and consumption), childcare, and surviving child rates have significant roles in the evolution of fertility choice over time. Thus, ignoring these factors in explaining agents’ fertility fails to provide a full explanation for the fertility evolution. Overall, by analyzing a richer but tractable preference structure, this study provides new insights into agents’ fertility choice and thus enhances understanding of the evolution of fertility.