Log in

Linkages and changing factor use in Indian economy: Implications of emerging trade pattern

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Social and Economic Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Globally, a greater component of trade in intermediates—parts and components—is a characteristic of the changing paradigm of international trade. Consequently, alongside the increasing trade openness of the Indian economy, the access to international factors of production has increased through their embodied use during the production of intermediates that are imported. Thus, the emerging trade pattern has the potential to impact the use of factors of production of domestic origin through linkages in the internal economy. This paper makes an assessment of the changing intensity of use of the two factors of production, viz., labor (L) and capital (K), in the economy. The analysis aims to provide an estimate of the impact of import utilization on the use of labor and capital. In the backdrop of a generally declining employment intensity, the employment foregone effect from the use of imported intermediate inputs is observed to have worsened over the period of study. Ironically, this has contributed to lower domestic employment, even in the traditionally labor-intensive sectors. The employment effect of import utilizations is also reflected in the declining share of labor income. The use of capital embodied in imported intermediates has contributed to increasing the capital intensity of the economy despite the low domestic capital investment. This underscores a greater dependency on capital-intensive imports. While import reliance has increased for both employment and the capital goods through their embodied use in the imported inputs, the dependency on imported capital has been stronger. A higher relative use of capital (K-to-L) indicates that the production method is relatively capital-intensive, thus requiring more capital goods and investment. The findings resolve the puzzle of India’s increasing relative use of capital alongside a slowdown of domestic investments in productive capital. The deficit on domestic investment has been compensated through import utilizations of capital goods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. India’s GFCF (as % of GDP) has increased from 23.4% during 1994 to 28.8% during 2019 (World Bank 2021). It has continued to be higher than the comparable figure for the world during the period. The world GFCF (as % GDP) for the world has been lower at 23.8% during 2019.

  2. It may be noted that productivity studies tend to discuss the use of raw material, energy and services as additional factors of production. In the present context, these have been accounted through the measurement of direct and indirect use within an I–O framework. Another factor of production, namely innovation and entrepreneurship, is often dealt in qualitative analysis due to unavailability of data in an economy-wide framework.

  3. While certain sectors such as construction and power utilities can be argued as non-tradable due to a predominantly domestic disposition of output, their input structure is nevertheless dependent on the use of imported inputs. For instance, construction machinery is largely imported and coal for electricity generation is sourced from abroad. Therefore, even the non-tradable sectors are implicitly impacted from the channels of trade.

  4. The impact of differentiated imports by the country of origin is recognized through the substitution possibilities (Armington 1969) and the Multi-Region Input-Output tables (MRIOs) that track country-specific imports. Overtime, many MRIOs have been compiled e.g., those available from the GTAP, ADB, European Commission, and UNCTAD. Their application is more suited through contribution to a Computable General Equilibrium based study, where the sector-level effects for each country are captured through changes in commodity and factor prices. However, in the present context it suffices to obtain separate matrices for the domestically produced and imported inputs at the country-level.

  5. However, the results may not be significantly different for countries with minimal proportion of re-exports.

  6. Therefore, summation of the shares of labor and capital income may not add up to 1 for a given sector, as would be expected in a Cobb–Douglas production function under constant returns to scale. In that sense it may not be necessary that a capital using effect is noted alongside a labor saving effect, as in the paper.

  7. Some studies also measure employment through the time duration in man-hours/days/years.

  8. For instance, the estimation of capital stock requires strong assumptions related to aging structure of fixed assets across industries and over different times (ILO 2009).

  9. Generally, richer countries are technologically advanced and have higher stocks of capital.

  10. Even though trading partners and the basket of trade is expected to have changed over time due to the participation in global production chains, the combined effect of all the changes is adequately captured in the production technology (reflected in demand and supply relations of the I–O data) and the transformation of the economic structure (reflected through output and the factor use). Since structural transformation is gradual over time, the underlying structure of the economy is considered valid during the medium-run period of upto 5–7 years.

  11. Henceforth, public administration & defense is excluded from the discussion due to the non-comparability in the compilation of the sector as reported in IOTTs for the two time periods.

  12. While the analysis of employment intensity in the preceding sub-section does confirm the decline in job intensity, the analysis of a skill-based employment effect is beyond the present scope. Nevertheless, the composite effect for all skill types can be seen in the impact on labor income share.

  13. Capital intensity here refers to the share of capital income.

  14. A similar analysis on relative use of factors is undertaken in the following subsection.

  15. Although the retrospective tax law has been recently scrapped in 2021, its effect would be seen in the future.

  16. K-to-L ratio for 1993–94 is computed from the factor use reported in column (2) of Tables 2 and 3 for the broad activity groups. Similarly, K-to-L ratio for 2015–16 is based on values reported in column (5) of the tables. A separate table is avoided for reasons of repetitiveness.

  17. Kanan and Raveendran (2009) focus on organized manufacturing sector.

  18. Gross output of capital goods increased by 2% between 2010 and 2015.

  19. Diagonlaization of vectors is required for conformity in matrix operations.

  20. Details of the KLEMS data have been discussed earlier in the paper.  

  21. The total requirement matrix, S, differs from the total requirement matrix, L. While the former provides total requirements of domestically produced inputs, the latter provides total inputs requirements inclusive of imported inputs. Therefore, the interaction of factor coefficients with the elements of S provides total domestic factor requirements.

  22. Employment refers to number of person employed, while labor and capital as factors of production are measured through the income shares.

  23. The column vector \(E=\left[{E}_{j}\right]\) represents the export value for sectors where j = 1,2,..,n.

References

  • Abraham V, & Sasikumar SK (2019) Declining wage share in India’s organized manufacturing sector: trends, patterns and determinants, ILO Asia-Pacific working paper series

  • Acemoglu D (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Q J Econ 113(4):1055–1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • All India Association of Industries. https://www.aiaiindia.com/capital-goods.html#:~:text=Presently%2C%20India%20imports%20around%2040,%25%20from%20the%20present%2040%25 (accessed October 1, 2020)

  • Armington P (1969) A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Pap 16(1):159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Central Statistical Organization (2000) Input–Output transactions Table 1993–94, Ministry of statistics and programme implementation, Government of India

  • Chadha R, Saluja MR & Sivamani G (2020) Input output transactions table: India 2015–16, Brookings India, discussion paper, January 012020

  • McKinsey & Company (2016) Accelerating growth in the Indian capital goods sector, prepared for FICCI capital goods committee

  • Das DK, & Kalit G (2009) Do labor intensive industries generate employment? Evidence from firm level survey in India. Indian council for research on international economic relations working paper, 237

  • Das DK, Erumban AA, Aggarwal S & Das PC (2015) Measuring productivity at the industry level the India KLEMS database, Data Manual 2015 (Version 2)

  • Das DK, Erumban AA, Aggarwal S & Das PC (2018) Measuring productivity at the industry level, The India Database, Data Manual 2017, Version 4, Delhi School of Economics

  • Das DK, Erumban AA, Aggarwal S & Das PC (2019) KELMS database, Version 6, RBI

  • Diwan I (2001) Debt as Sweat: Labor, financial crises, and the globalization of capital, The World Bank

  • Export-Import Bank of India (2014) Indian capital goods industry: a sector study, Occasional Paper No. 169

  • Goldar B (2009) Impact of trade on employment generation in manufacturing in India, Institute of Economic Growth, Working Paper Series No. E/297/2009

  • Government of India (2016) National Capital Goods Policy 2016, Ministry of Heavy Industries & Public Enterprises

  • Gulhane S & Turukmane R (2017) Effect of make in India on textile sector. J Text Eng Fash Technol 3:551–555

    Google Scholar 

  • Horridge M, McDougall R, Narayanan B & Terrie L, Walmsley (2008) Exercises in contributing I–O tables to the GTAP data base

  • International Labour Organization. (2009) Towards an employment strategy for India

  • Ju J, Justin YL & Wang Y (2009) Technology choice, industrial dynamics, and economic growth

  • Kannan KP & Raveendran G (2009) Growth sans employment: a quarter century of jobless growth in India’s organised manufacturing. Econ Pol Wkly 44(10):80–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapoor R (2014) Creating jobs in India’s organised manufacturing sector, Indian council for research on international economic relations, working paper 286

  • Leontief W (1956) Factor proportions and the structure of American trade: further theoretical and empirical analysis. Rev Econ Stat 38(4):386–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin JY (2003) Development strategy, viability, and economic convergence. Econ Dev Cult Change 51(2):277–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patnaik I & Pundit M (2014) Is India’s long-term trend growth declining?, ADB economics working paper series, No. 424, December 2014

  • Pollin R (2000) Globalization, inequality and financial instability: confronting the Marx, Keynes and Polanyi problems in advanced capitalist economies, Political Economy Research Institute Working Paper No. 8, Amherst, University of Massachusetts

  • Riedel J (1975) Factor proportions, linkages and the open develo** economy. Rev Econ Stat 57(4):487–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen K & Das DK (2015) Where have all the workers gone? Puzzle of declining labour intensity in organised Indian manufacturing. Econ Polit Wkly 50:108–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen K (2008) Trade, FDI and industrial transformation in India, Paper prepared for research workshop ‘Emerging trends and patterns of trade and investment in Asia’, Ninth Global Development Network Conference, Brisbane, Australia.

  • Sen K (2014) The puzzle of declining labour intensity in organised Indian manufacturing, Ideas for India, April 25

  • Tandon A (2020) Revisiting factor proportions in the Indian economy - a study of tradable sectors. Econ Polit Wkly LV 3:47–54

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. Undated. The OECD input-output database, Part 1, sources and methods

  • USDA (2019) India's food processing sector- a sunrise sector, GAIN Report Number: IN9041

  • Veeramani C (2016) Inter-linkages between exports and employment in India. Occasional Paper (179), EXIM Bank of India

  • World Bank (2021) World Development Indicators, accessed online

  • WTO-IDE-JETRO (2013) Trade patterns and global value chains in East Asia: from trade in goods to trade in tasks

Download references

Funding

This work draws funding support under the Indian Council for Social Science Research project: IMPRESS/P574/01/2018-19/ICSSR.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anjali Tandon.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

I declare that the manuscript has been submitted solely to the journal and that it is not submitted elsewhere. The author does not have any conflict of interests to declare.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1 Model formulation

A1.1 Basics of the input–output model

The I–O model represents intersectoral linkages through demand and supply relationships among sectors of the economy. The interactions are essentially transaction flows from a sector i to another sector j indicating value of commodity transaction from the ith input providing sector to the jth output producing sector. The mathematical representation of the model is conventionally through the use of matrices. The cost structure of a producing sector is presented in a column providing commodity flows of all inputs (material and service) used. The column also includes expenditure on account of the use of factors of production (i.e., value addition as a composite of labor and capital) and net taxes paid by the sector. The output supply of a sector under consideration can be consumed as intermediate input for sectors of the economy, or as a final good. The supply distribution is presented through the flows within a row corresponding to the sector.

Consider the economy with n (a positive integer) sectors inclusive of the production and service activities. Thus, in an economy the output of each sector (column vector X) is either consumed as an intermediate input (matrix Z of transaction flows) in the production process of another sector, or is consumed as a final good (column vector Y). Elements of the matrix Z (of size nXn) are Xij representing the intersectoral intermediate flows from sector i to the sector j as follows:

$$Z = \left[ {X_{ij} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {X_{11} } & \cdots & {X_{1n} } \\ \vdots & \ddots & \vdots \\ {X_{n1} } & \cdots & {X_{nn} } \\ \end{array} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(1)
$${\text{Similarly}},\;X = \left[ {X_{i} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {X_{1} } \\ \vdots \\ {X_{n} } \\ \end{array} } \right] \;{\text{and}}\;Y = \left[ {Y_{i} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {Y_{1} } \\ \vdots \\ {Y_{n} } \\ \end{array} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;i = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(2)

The disposition of total output is compactly written in a matrix notation as:

$$\underbrace {Z}_{{{\text{intermediate}}\;{\text{consumption}} }}*\underbrace {i}_{{{\text{identity}}\;{\text{column}}\;{\text{vector}}}} + \underbrace {Y}_{{{\text{final}}\;{\text{use}}}} = \underbrace {X}_{{{\text{total}}\;{\text{output}}}}$$
(3)

The intersectoral relations in the economy are represented through the technical coefficient matrix, A (nXn) whose ijth element shows the amount of input from the ith sector required to produce one unit output of the jth sector. The matrix A is also called as the direct coefficient matrix or technology matrix as it shows the dependence of inter-industry flows on total output of each sector of the economy and is defined as:

$$A = \left[ {a_{{{\text{ij}}}} } \right] ,\;{\text{where}}\;a_{{{\text{ij}}}} = \frac{{X_{{{\text{ij}}}} }}{{X_{j} }},\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(4)
$${\text{Thus}},\;A = Z*\hat{X}^{ - 1} \mathop \Rightarrow \limits_{{}} Z = A*\hat{X}$$
(5)

where \(\widehat{\mathrm{X}}\) is a diagonal matrix of the sector outputs.Footnote 19

Using Eq. (5) in Eq. (3), the output is expressed in terms of technology matrix as:

$$X = \left( {I - A} \right)^{ - 1} *Y$$
(6)
$${\text{Let}},\;L = \left( {I - A} \right)^{ - 1} = \left[ {r_{{{\text{ij}}}} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(7)

The matrix L is called the Leontief inverse and shows the dependence of gross output (X) on final demand (Y). It is also referred to as the total requirement matrix and is inclusive of the indirect effects which occur due to multiple and nested rounds of interrelationship among sectors.

A1.2 Separating imported and domestically produced intermediate requirements

The separation of imported and the domestically produced intermediate inputs, as needed for implementation of the methodology adopted in the present paper, requires separating the transaction flows (Xij) into two additive components. Individual transactions in the intermediate matrix are expressed as the sum of corresponding domestic and import flows. Thus, we write the following:

$$X_{{{\text{ij}}}} = D_{{{\text{ij}}}} + M_{{{\text{ij}}}}$$
(8)

Accordingly, the corresponding output coefficients of domestic and imports requirements can be written as:

$$D = \left[ {d_{{{\text{ij}}}} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;d_{{{\text{ij}}}} = \frac{{D_{{{\text{ij}}}} }}{{X_{j} }},\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(9)
$${\text{and}}\;M = \left[ {m_{{{\text{ij}}}} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;m_{{{\text{ij}}}} = \frac{{M_{{{\text{ij}}}} }}{{X_{j} }},\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(10)
$${\text{Thus}}\;{\text{referring}}\;{\text{to}}\;{\text{Eq}}\;\left( 8 \right),\;a_{{{\text{ij}}}} = d_{{{\text{ij}}}} + m_{{{\text{ij}}}}$$
(11)

Define, the total domestic requirement matrix of inputs as

$$S = \left( {I - D} \right)^{ - 1} = \left[ {s_{{{\text{ij}}}} } \right],\;{\text{where}}\;i,\;j = 1,2, \ldots ,n$$
(12)

An element sij provides the total input requirements of all domestically produced inputs (material and services) from sector i for a unit output in the jth sector.

A1.3 Estimating factor proportions

Factor requirements of domestically produced inputs

In an I–O framework, the direct factor coefficients are required to initiate the estimation of total factor use in a given sector. The direct factor coefficients, \({f}_{j}^{k}\), measure the amount of the kth production factor directly used for a unit output of the jth sector. For instance, a direct labor (capital) coefficient of a sector measures the amount of labor (capital) used directly in the sector activity. Since this information is not explicitly available for different factors of production from within the IOTT, the direct coefficient values are sourced from the KLEMS database of the RBI, 2020.Footnote 20 These coefficients are then integrated into the I-O model through their interaction with the total requirement matrix, S.Footnote 21 Details are discussed as follows.

For a kth factor of production, consider the diagonal matrix of direct coefficients, \(\widehat{{f}^{k}}\) as shown in Eq. (15) where k = employment, labor, capital.Footnote 22

$$\widehat{{f}^{k}}=\left[\begin{array}{c}{f}_{1}^{k}\\ 0\\ \begin{array}{c}\vdots \\ 0\end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}0\\ {f}_{2}^{k}\\ \begin{array}{c}\vdots \\ 0\end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}\dots \\ \dots \\ \begin{array}{c}\ddots \\ \dots \end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}0\\ 0\\ \begin{array}{c}0\\ {f}_{n}^{k}\end{array}\end{array}\right]$$
(13)

Let \({\mathrm{F}}_{j}^{k}\) denote the total use of kth factor required for production of one unit output of the jth sector. Following the methodology suggested by Riedel (1975), the value of \({\mathrm{F}}_{j}^{k}\) is obtained by interacting (multiplying) \(\widehat{{f}^{k}}\) with the total domestic requirement matrix S and adding across rows within a column. Thus, for all k and j = 1,2,…,n, we write the following equation:

$$\left[ {F_{j}^{k} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {F_{1}^{k} } & {F_{2}^{k} } & {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \ldots & {F_{n}^{k} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \widehat{{f^{k} }}*S$$
$$\scriptsize = \underbrace {{\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {f_{1}^{k} } \\ 0 \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ 0 \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ {f_{2}^{k} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ 0 \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} \ldots \\ \ldots \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { \ddots } \\ \ldots \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ 0 \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 0 \\ {f_{n}^{k} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right]}}_{direct \ use\ of \ kth\ factor \ per\ unit \ output \ of \ sector\ j}$$
$$ *\underbrace {{\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {s_{11} } \\ {s_{21} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {s_{n1} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} {s_{12} } \\ {s_{22} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {s_{n2} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} \ldots \\ \ldots \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { \ddots } \\ \ldots \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} {s_{1n} } \\ {s_{21} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {s_{nn} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right]}}_{total\ domestic\ input\ from \ sector\ i \ required \ for\ a\ unit \ output \ of \ sector \ j}$$
$$ = \underbrace {{\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {f_{1}^{k} s_{11} } \\ {f_{2}^{k} s_{21} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {f_{n}^{k} s_{n1} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} {f_{1}^{k} s_{12} } \\ {f_{2}^{k} s_{22} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {f_{n}^{k} s_{n2} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} \ldots \\ \ldots \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { \ddots } \\ \ldots \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} \begin{array}{*{20}c} {f_{1}^{k} s_{1n} } \\ {f_{2}^{k} s_{21} } \\ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \vdots \\ {f_{n}^{k} s_{nn} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right]}}_{use\ of\ kth\ factor \ in\ domestic\ production\ of \ input\ i \ used\ in\ one\ unit\ of \ sector \ j}$$
(14)
$$= \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} f_{i}^{k} s_{i1} } & {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} f_{i}^{k} s_{i2} } & {\begin{array}{*{20}c} \ldots & {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} f_{i}^{k} s_{in} } \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right]$$
(15)

Summation of the elements within a column of the matrix on RHS of Eq. (15) provides \({F}_{j}^{k}\), as the total (direct and indirect) requirement of the kth factor through its use in production of all inputs used in one unit output of the sector represented in the column j. Equation (15) is further used to estimate total factor requirement to meet the final demand or any sub-component of final demand, e.g., exports (E).Footnote 23 Factor requirement for of the kth factor to meet the export demand, \({F}_{E}^{k}\) as given as:

$${F}_{E}^{k}=\left[{F}_{j}^{k}\right]*\widehat{E}=\left[\begin{array}{ccc}\sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{i1}& \sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{i2}& \begin{array}{cc}\dots & \sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{in}\end{array}\end{array}\right]*\left[\begin{array}{c}{E}_{1 }\\ 0\\ \begin{array}{c}\vdots \\ 0\end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}0\\ {E}_{2 }\\ \begin{array}{c}\vdots \\ 0\end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}\dots \\ \dots \\ \begin{array}{c}\ddots \\ \dots \end{array}\end{array}\begin{array}{c}0\\ 0\\ \begin{array}{c}0\\ {E}_{n}\end{array}\end{array}\right]$$
(16)

Thus, we have,

$${F}_{E}^{k}=\left[\begin{array}{ccc}\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{i1}\right)*{E}_{1 }& \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{i2}\right)*{E}_{2 }& \begin{array}{cc}\dots & \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{in}\right)\end{array}\end{array}*{E}_{n}\right]$$
(17)

The jth element of the row vector in the RHS of Eq. (17) represents the total factor use to meet export demand in the jth sector. Summing over the columns gives requirement of the kth factor to meet the overall exports in the economy, \({F}_{E}^{k}\) as:

$${F}_{E}^{k}=\sum_{j=1}^{n}\left(\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n}{f}_{i}^{k}{s}_{i1}\right)*{E}_{j}\right)$$
(18)

Factor requirements of imported inputs

On the other hand, factor use in imports is not explicitly known due to the unavailability of a foreign production technology matrix, separately for each import partner. Thus, we proxy the factor use in imports through measurement of factors in an equivalent export production (used to earn foreign exchange for purchasing imports). Thus, even though the total requirement coefficients used pertain to domestic technology, their use in the production of the export equivalent of imports provides the required estimate of imported factor use. The proxy computation requires to express imports as a function of — (i) export, and (ii) the production technology used in process of export production of an amount equivalent to imports.

In order to account for factor use in imported inputs, define \({M}_{i}=\sum_{j=1}^{n}{m}_{ji}\) as the direct requirement of all imported inputs (denoted by subscript j) in one unit production of output in the ith sector. Multiplying Mi with sij provides the (direct and indirect) import requirement in the ith input used in one unit output of the jth sector. Summing over all inputs (index i) provides the requirement of all imported inputs for a unit output of jth sector, Mj. This is given by the following expression:

$${M}_{j}=\sum_{i=1}^{n}\left({M}_{i}{s}_{ij}\right)=\sum_{i=1}^{n}\left(\sum_{j=1}^{n}{m}_{ji}{s}_{ij}\right)$$
(19)

Total import requirement for a unit export from the economy is based on the structure of the export basket and is represented by ej as the export share of jth sector. Accordingly, imports requirement for producing export, ej, of the jth sector are given by Mj*ej. Further, summation over sector-wise requirements provides total import requirement for the production of exports as shown in Eq. (20).

$$M_{E} = \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{n} \left( {M_{j} *e_{j } } \right) = \underbrace {{\sum\limits_{j - 1}^{n} {\underbrace {{\left( {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} \left( {\underbrace {{\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} \underbrace {{m_{ji} }}_{A}*S_{ij} }}_{B}} \right)*e_{j} } \right)}}_{C}} }}_{D}$$
(20)

where the expressions have the following representation:

  • A: direct import use of jth input in a unit output of ith sector.

  • B: direct and indirect import requirement of all inputs per unit output of jth sector.

  • C: import requirement for export of jth sector.

  • D: sum of import requirements for all exports.

Equation (20) provides an export equivalence of imports. It shows the amount of imports purchased with the foreign exchange earned from the exports. In other words, ME is the amount of exports (exchanged) for imports. It may be clarified here that although value of imports are directly available, their factor use cannot be assessed directly due to difference in production technology in the country of origin. Therefore, an export proxy of the import value is used to estimate the factor equivalence in the domestic production.

Estimating import use in production of exports

The use of factor imports in the production of additional exports to exchange for the imported inputs is given by \({F}_{E}^{k}* {M}_{E}\) in the first round of import use. However, the production of exports (to finance the imports) in turn requires the use of imported inputs. This imposes a requirement of \({M}_{E}* {M}_{E}\) units of import, entailing an export equivalent of \(\left({F}_{E}^{k}* {M}_{E}\right)*{M}_{E}\) to finance the additional imports. This nesting of import use gives rise to a second round of requirements and continues further. Similarly, the effect of following rounds is measured by multiplying successive terms with \({M}_{E}\). Thus, the multiple round effect of import use is:

$${F}_{E}^{k}+\left({F}_{E}^{k}* {M}_{E}\right)+\left({F}_{E}^{k}* {M}_{E}*{M}_{E}\right)+\dots =\frac{{F}_{E}^{k}}{1-{M}_{E}}$$
(21)

since 0 \(\le {M}_{E}\le 1\)

It may be noted that the ratio on the RHS of Eq. (21) is a constant, independent of any sector. However, the ratio is different for a given factor of production. The ratio is the value of kth factor required to produce one unit of export in exchange for import. On multiplying the ratio with the import requirement in the jth sector (Mj), we get the factor use equivalent of import.

Factor requirements due to domestic and imported all inputs

The estimate of actual factor use of the kth factor in the jth sector, \({\tilde{F }}_{j}^{k}\), is the sum of – (i) factor use in the production of all domestically produced intermediate inputs (\({F}_{j}^{k})\)(using Eq. (18)), and (ii) factor use in the imports of jth sector (\({M}_{j})\), which is estimated by multiplying Mj with multiple round effects of factor use in production of exports to (earn foreign) exchange to pay for imported inputs (in Eq. (21)).

$${\tilde{F }}_{j}^{k}={F}_{j}^{k}+{M}_{j}\left(\frac{{F}_{E}^{k}}{1-{M}_{E}}\right)$$
(22)

Equation (22) is used separately for the each of the factors of production.

Appendix 2 Description of sectors and broad groups

S. No

Description

1

Agriculture, hunting, forestry, and fishing

2

Mining and quarrying

3

Food products, beverages and tobacco

4

Textiles, textile products, leather and footwear

5

Wood and products of wood

6

Pulp, paper, paper products, printing and publishing

7

Coke, refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel

8

Chemicals and chemical products

9

Rubber and plastic products

10

Other nonmetallic mineral products

11

Basic metals and fabricated metal products

12

Machinery, nec

13

Electrical and optical equipment

14

Transport equipment

15

Manufacturing, nec; recycling

16

Electricity, gas and water supply

17

Construction

18

Trade

19

Hotels and restaurants

20

Transport and storage

21

Post and telecommunication

22

Financial services

23

Business service

24

Public administration and defense; compulsory social security

25

Education

26

Health and social work

27

Other services

 

Groups

1–27

All

1

Agriculture

2

Mining

3–15

Manufacturing

16–27

Services

  1. nec not elsewhere classified.
  2. Source Das et al. 2015.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tandon, A. Linkages and changing factor use in Indian economy: Implications of emerging trade pattern. J. Soc. Econ. Dev. 24, 266–294 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-022-00190-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-022-00190-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation