Log in

Pareto and pure economics: analyses subsequently accepted and others neglected

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Pure economics, as presented by Pareto in the Manual of Political Economy, has only a scientific purpose to be evaluated according to the agreement with reality, takes into account only economic actions, and its object is the determination of equilibrium, represented by the compatibility of agents’ choices. The choices depend on the agents’ tastes (preferences), the obstacles (constraints) to which they are subject, and the conditions in which they operate. Pareto’s pure economics does not have the purpose of determining prices, it is therefore not a theory of value, since exchanges can have variable prices. Pareto distinguishes agents into three types: those without market power whose choice is obliged to belong to a pre-assigned path (constraint), agents with market power who impose to the first type agents a path, and agents who represent the socialist state. The two main contributions introduced by Pareto in pure economics and subsequently accepted are discussed. They are the adoption of the ordinal function of utility and the notion of Pareto optimum. The general equilibrium theory presented by Pareto does not consider only, or even principally, the competitive equilibrium, but also includes other market rules, such as monopolies, duopolies, cartels, and the collectivist economy. Particular importance is given by Pareto to production with big overheads, which determine a decreasing average cost. The analysis proposed by Pareto anticipates many results which were successively introduced in the economic literature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Pareto uses the term ophelimity for reasons already indicated in the Cours 1896–1897 and synthetically in Chap. III, § 30; today utility is commonly used. Ophelimity and utility as synonyms in this paper, even if not they were such for Pareto.

  2. Pareto sometimes applies to ordinal utility, especially when he considers its second and third derivatives (for example, in the App.Fr. § 47), properties that have meaning only for the cardinal one. In this regard, and on the question of whether Pareto is completely ordinalist or has remained substantially cardinalist, an issue on which there is a wide diversity of opinions, see, for example, Bruni and Guala 2001.

  3. For instance, Mas-Colell, Whinson and Green 1995, Chap.I, pp.5–14.

  4. In the modern representation of the competitive general equilibrium, agents are price-takers and the theory of value is sought: for example, Debreu 1959.

  5. On general equilibrium theory without prices, see Gay 2006.

  6. The analysis of the collectivist state provided by Pareto had been in some ways preceded by von Wieser 1889 (1893), who, however, was only interested in showing how it is necessary to charge a cost to the use of capital goods also in this type of economy, and it was followed by the famous article by Barone 1908 (2012), based on Pareto’s approach.

  7. For instance, Debreu 1959 and Mas-Colell et al. 1995.

  8. I presented the problem of dynamics, also considering in detail the confusion between “static” and “stationarity” prevailing until the 1930s, in Montesano 1972 (2012).

  9. In this regard A. Zanni E.N.3 in Pareto 2014.

  10. On the distribution of incomes as obtained and formulated by Pareto, see Pareto 1896-7, §§ 950–972, and Pareto 1967. Chipman 1976, 1999, Chap. 4.gives an accurate presentation of Pareto’s research on this distribution, the discussions that arose (in particular, with Edgeworth), and the subsequent research.

  11. See, for instance, Gabaix 1999.

  12. See, for instance, Ijiri and Simon 1975.

  13. Pareto introduces in the App.Fr. § 5 the marginal rates of substitution (without giving them this name) by writing: “we shall therefore seek to determine by what positive amount, \({\Delta _1}x\), the variable x would have to increase in order to offset the decrease represented by the negative amount \(\Delta y\); in the same way, we shall determine the \({\Delta _2}x\) that corresponds to \(\Delta z\), etc.”

  14. An economist, before Pareto, who indicated the presence of characteristics of the utility function that are of no use in economics, including cardinality, was Fisher 1892; in particular in Part II § 8 (p.89). Marchionatti and Gambino 1997 present the evolution of the Paretian approach to utility, and the comparison with Fisher statement.

  15. Considering a price-taker agent, the demand functions represent the choices, and the first author to introduce the conditions of integrability for this situation was Antonelli 1886. Hurwicz 1971 provided an exhaustive analysis of the integrability of demand functions.

  16. Montesano 2006 and Scapparone 2006 and 2009 on this aspect of Pareto’s analysis.

  17. These conditions are indicated in a simple way by Montesano 2022.

  18. Pareto is not at all clear, as Allais 1973; pp.1072–1076, points out.

  19. As, moreover, already indicated by Debreu 1951.

  20. For instance, Mas-Colell et al. 1995; p.308.

  21. Pareto 1913 and Trattato di Sociologia 1936 (§§ 2128–2139).

  22. See, for instance, Mas-Colell et al. 1995; p.825, where they write: “In this section we assume that the policy maker has an explicit and consistent criterion to carry off this task [i.e., to choose the social policy]. Specifically, we assume that this criterion is given by a social welfare function \(W(u)=W({u_1},...,{u_I})\) that aggregates individuals’ utilities into social utilities.” In the footnote, they add: “This approach to welfare economics was first taken by Bergson (1938) and Samuelson (1947)”, without however indicating Pareto’s anticipation. Pareto’s anticipation is noted by Chipman 1976, 1999, Chap. 1.

  23. I examined this market regime, overlooked by the economic literature, in Montesano 2012.

  24. There is certainly no lack of analyses in the economic literature concerning productions with big overhead costs. See, for example, Hotelling 1938; Boiteux 1956 and Mosca 2008. Dupuit 1844 was probably the first economist to deal with this problem.

  25. For instance, a global analysis is in Debreu 1959; pp. 90–97.

  26. Stationary price expectations are, for example, assumed in the cobweb theorem, the history and analysis of which is described by Mordecai 1938.

  27. Walras does not explicitly consider expectations when he uses them in the theory of capitalization and credit. However, he writes equations that use stationary expectations: Walras 1900 (1954) Eq. (8) in § 249 of the IV ed. In this regard Montesano 2008; p. 88.

  28. One of the first economists to introduce expectations in the theory of general equilibrium was La Volpe 1936 (in this regard, Montesano 2018b). La Volpe anticipates Hicks 1939 both about expectations and the temporariness of static equilibrium. Moreover, the rediscovery by Hicks that static equilibrium is temporary does not mean that this was not already the case for Walras and, above all, for Pareto: in this regard, Donzelli 1986; pp. 264–268 and 404–406.

References

  • Allais M (1943) (1952, 1994) A la recherche d’une discipline économiquePremière partieL’économie pure, Paris: Ateliers Industria; 2a ed. 1952, Traité d’économie pure, Paris: Imprimerie Nationale; 3° ed. 1994. Paris: C. Juglar

  • Allais M (1973) La théorie générale des surplus et l’apport fondamental de Vilfredo Pareto. Revue d’Economie Politique 83(6):1044–1097

    Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli GB (1886) (1951, 1971) Sulla teoria matematica dell’economia politica, Pisa (ripubblicato sul Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, N.S. 10, 1951, pp. 233–263); (Engl. trans.), On the mathematical theory of political economy, in (J.S. Chipman, L. Hurwicz, M.K. Richter and H.F. Sonnenschein eds,) Preferences, utility, and demand. A Minnesota symposium, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1971, pp. 333–364

  • Barone F (1908) (2012) Il ministro della produzione nello stato collettivista, Giornale degli Economisti 37, pp. 267–293 e 391–414; (Engl. trans.) The ministry of production in the collectivist state, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 71 (2–3), 2012, pp. 75–112

  • Bergson A (1938) A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics. Quart J Econ 52(2):310–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boiteux M (1956) Sur la gestion des monopoles publics astreints a l’équilibre budgetaire. Econometrica 24(1):22–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruni L, Guala F (2001) Pareto and the epistemological foundations of rational choice. Hist Polit Econ 33(1):21–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chipman JS (1976) (1999) The Paretian heritage, Revue européenne des sciences sociales et Cahiers Vilfredo Pareto, Tome XIV, 37, pp. 65–173, and in (Wood and McLure eds,) Vilfredo Pareto. Critical assessments of leading economists, London: Routledge, 1999, Vol. II, pp. 157–257

  • Debreu G. (1951) The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19:pp273–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1959) Theory of value. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Donzelli F (1986) Il Concetto Di Equilibrio Nella Teoria Economica Neoclassica. La Nuova Italia Scientifica, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Dooley PC (1983) Slutsky’s equation is Pareto’s solution. Hist Polit Econ 15:513–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dupuit J (1995) 1844 De la mesure de l’utilité des travaux publics 1844, in Revue française d’économie 10(2), 1995, pp. 55–94

  • Fisher I (1892) Mathematical investigations in the theory of value and prices. Connecticut Academy, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix X (1999) Zipf’s law for cities: an explanation. Quart J Econ 114(3):739–767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gay A (2006) Equilibrium without prices: a central issue in Pareto’s Manuale. RISEC (International Rev Economics) 53(4):531–537

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1939) Value and capital, London: Oxford University Press; 2a ed. 1946

  • Hicks JR (1940) The valuation of the social income. Economica 7, pp. 105–124

  • Hicks JR (1975) Pareto and the economic optimum, in Convegno Internazionale Vilfredo Pareto (Roma 25–27 ottobre 1973), Atti dei Convegni Lincei 9, Roma: Accademia nazionale dei Lincei, pp. 19–28

  • Hicks JR, Allen RGD (1934) A reconsideration of the theory of value, Economica, N.S. 1, pp. 52–76 e 196–219

  • Hotelling H (1938) The general welfare in relation to problems of taxation and of railway and utility rates. Econometrica 6(3):242–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz L (1971) On the problem of integrability of demand functions, in (J.S. Chipman, L. Hurwicz, M.K. Richter and H.F. Sonnenschein eds,) Preferences, utility, and demand. A Minnesota symposium, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., pp.174–214

  • Ijiri Y, Simon HA (1975) Some distributions associated with Bose-Einstein statistics. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 72(5):1654–1657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1939) Welfare propositions of economics and interpersonal comparison of utility. Econ J 49:549–552

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Volpe G (1936) (1993) Studi sulla teoria dell’equilibrio economico dinamico generale, Napoli: Jovene. (Eng. trans.) Studies on the Theory of General Dynamic Economic Equilibrium. London: Macmillan, 1993

  • Lange O (1942) The foundations of welfare economics. Econometrica 10(3–4):215–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchionatti R, Gambino E (1997) Pareto and political economy as a science: methodological revolution and analytical advances in economic theory in the 1890s. J Polit Econ 105(6):1322–1348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green JR (1995) Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesano A (1972) (2012) La nozione di economia dinamica, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, NS 31(3–4), 1972, pp. 185–228; (Engl. trans.) The notion of dynamic economics, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 71 (2–3), 2012, pp. 297–334

  • Montesano A (2006) The Paretian theory of ophelimity in closed and open cycles. Hist Econ Ideas XIV/3:77–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesano A (2008) A restatement of Walras’ theories of Capitalisation and Money. His Econ Rev 47:86–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montesano A (2012) Price collusion with free entry: the parasitic competition. Int Rev Econ 59:41–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montesano A (2018a) A dual characterization of Pareto optimality, Italian Economic Journal 4(1), 2018, pp. 153–188

  • Montesano A (2018b) Il contributo di La Volpe alla teoria dinamica dell’economia. In: Billio M, Coronella S, Mio C, Sostero U (eds) Le discipline economiche e aziendali nei 150 anni di storia di ca’ Foscari. Edizioni Ca’ Foscari, Venezia, pp 193–203

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesano A (2022) On the economic foundations of decision theory. Theor Decis 93(3):563–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mordecai E (1938) The Cobweb Theorem. Quart J Econ 52(2):255–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mosca M (2008) On the origins of the concept of natural monopoly. Eur J History Economic Thought XV(2):317–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto V (1900) Sunto di alcuni capitoli di un nuovo trattato di economia pura del prof. Pareto, Giornale degli Economisti 20, pp. 216–235 e 511–549; (Engl. trans.) Summary of some chapters of a new treatise on pure economics by professor Pareto, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia 67/3, pp. 453–504

  • Pareto V (1902) Di un nuovo errore nello interpretare le teorie dell’economia matematica, Giornale degliEconomisti 25, pp. 401–433; (Engl. trans.) On a new error in the interpretation of the theories of mathematical economics, Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia 67/3, pp. 515–543

  • Pareto V (1906) 1909, 2006, 2014, Manuale di economia politica, con una introduzione alla scienza sociale, Milano: Società Editrice Libraria, 1906; trad. fr., Manuel d’économie politique, Paris: Giard et Brière, 1909; (a cura di A. Montesano, A. Zanni e L. Bruni) Manuale di economia politica, edizione critica, Milano: Università Bocconi Editore, 2006; (A. Montesano, A. Zanni, L. Bruni, J.S. Chipman and M. McLure eds.) Manual of political economy, A critical and variorum edition, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2014

  • Pareto V (1913) Il massimo di utilità per una collettività in sociologia, Giornale degli Economisti e Rivista di Statistica 46, pp. 337–341; (Engl. trans.) The community’s utility maximum in sociology, in (L. Pasinetti ed.) Italian economic papers, vol. I, Il Mulino and Oxford University Press, 1992, pp.39–43

  • Pareto V (1916) 1923, (1936), Trattato di sociologia generale, Firenze: Barbera, 1916, 2° ed. 1923; (Engl. trans.) The mind and society New York: Harcourt Brace and Co., 1936

  • Pareto V (1967) Écrits sur la courbe de la répartition de la richesse (in Oeuvres complètes: Tome III). Droz, Genève

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto V 1896–1897, Cours d’économie politique, Lausanne: Rouge, Vol. I, 1896 e Vol. II, 1897

  • Samuelson PA (1947) Foundations of economic analysis, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press; enlarged ed. 1983

  • Scapparone P (2006) The Paretian theory of ophelimity in closed and open cycles. A commentary. History Economic Ideas XIV 3:101–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Scapparone P (2009) Order of consumption and measurability of utility. In: Bruni L, Montesano A (eds) New essays on Pareto’s economic theory. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz H (1935) Interrelations of demand, price, and income. J Polit Econ 43:433–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky E (1915) Sulla teoria del bilancio del consumatore, Giornale degli Economisti e Rivista di Statistica 51, pp 1–26; (Engl. trans.) On the theory of the budget of the consumer, in (J. Stigler and K. E. Boulding eds.). Readings in price theory, Homewood: Irwin, 1952, pp. 27–56

  • Stackelberg von H (1933) Sulla teoria del duopolio e del polipolio. Rivista Italiana Di Statistica Economia E Finanza 11:275–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Volterra V, Richter MK and H.F. Sonnenschein (eds) (1906) (1971) L’economia matematica ed il nuovo manuale del prof. Pareto, Giornale degli Economisti 32, pp. 296–301; (Engl. trans.) Mathematical economics and professor Pareto’s new manual, in (J.S. Chipman, L. Hurwicz, Richter MK and H.F. Sonnenschein (eds),) Preferences, utility, and demand. A Minnesota symposium, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1971, pp. 365–369

  • von Wieser F (1893) 1889 Der natürliche Wert, Wien: A. Hölder, 1889; (Engl. trans.) Natural Value, London: Macmillan, 1893

  • Walras L (1900) (1954) Éléments d’économie politique pure, IV ed., Lausanne: Rouge, 1900; (Engl. trans.) Elements of pure economics, London: Allen and Unwin, 1954

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Pareto’s economic theory of Manual is presented showing all principal characters and innovations and clarifying some obscure treatments.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aldo Montesano.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Montesano, A. Pareto and pure economics: analyses subsequently accepted and others neglected. Int Rev Econ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-024-00462-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-024-00462-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation