Log in

Cash flow sensitivity of cash: when should we use it to measure financial constraints?

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Since Almeida et al. (J Financ 59:1777–1804, 2004), there has been a long debate on whether the cash flow sensitivity of cash (CFSC) measures financial constraints. Like all measures of financial constraints, CFSC is not a perfect one. Thus, how to measure financial constraints with CFSC effectively is an important issue. This paper shows that when a firm does not save through external financing, the CFSC can be effectively used to measure financial constraints. However, for firms saving from external financing, CFSC does not effectively measure financial constraints, especially when firms use external funds as substitutes for internal ones. The reason is that CFSC does not only reveal the propensity to save from cash flows but also the internal-external financing relation, which is not necessarily linked to financial constraints. Two identification methods are used to confirm our findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Germany)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Baum et al. (2011), Chen et al. (2012), Chen and Wang (2012), Erel et al. (2015), Itzkowitz (2015), Meng et al. (2020).

  2. Literature also show a decline and disappearance of the investment-cash flow sensitivity during the 2008 credit crunch (Chen et al. 2012).

  3. Note that to replicate results in Almeida et al. (2004), \(\Delta CASH\) and CF are scaled by current total assets. The estimates of the coefficients do not change significantly if we scale the variables with the total assets at the beginning of the period.

  4. There is much evidence supporting the existence of these economies of scale (Mulligan 1997; Bates et al. 2009). For example, larger firms hold less cash because of economies of scale with the transaction motive.

  5. They extract historical headquarter locations from WRDS SEC Analytics Suite and hand-collect the historical headquarter locations from the Moody’s Manuals (later Mergent Manuals) and Dun & Bradstreet’s Million Dollar Directory (later bought by Mergent)

  6. Fortunately, the University of Notre Dame’s Software Repository for Accounting and Finance provides the augmented 10-X header dataset: https://sraf.nd.edu/data/augmented-10-x-header-data/.

  7. All accounting data are CPI-adjusted into 1971 dollars.

  8. WW index and HP index are measured with the following methods:

    $$\begin{aligned} WW&=-0.091CF-0.062DIVPOS+0.021LEV-0.044SIZE+0.102ISG-0.035SG \\ HP&=-0.737SIZE+0.043SIZE^2-0.040AGE \end{aligned}$$

    where CF is the ratio of cash flow to total assets, LEV is the ratio of long-term debt to total assets, DIVPOS is a dummy indicating positive dividends, SIZE is the natural log of total assets, AGE is the number of years preceding the observation year that the firm has a non-missing stock price on the Compustat file, ISG is the firm’s 3-digit industry sales growth, and SG is the firm sales growth.

  9. KZ index is not included as in Almeida et al. (2004), the financially constrained firms classified with KZ index do not show a positive CFSC.

  10. The financing deficit is defined as the growth in assets less the growth in current liabilities less the growth in retained earnings.

  11. We acknowledge that there is a small proportion of firms that show negative correlations between cash savings and net external financing. Due to the lack of theoretical foundation, we do not consider the situation where the correlation coefficient is strongly negative.

  12. We also calculate the 15-year rolling correlation coefficient between cash savings and external financing to capture time-variant firm heterogeneity. In addition, we use \(\pm 0.2\) as cutoffs to ensure that firms in either group have correlation coefficient estimates that are statistically reliable. Alternative cutoffs are used as robustness checks to alleviate the potential measurement error associated with small sample estimations of the correlation coefficient (See Table 14).

  13. To compute this variable, we exclude firms when the denominator (the sum of cash flow) is negative to ensure that the weight is increasing in the amount of cash flow (Baker and Wurgler 2002).

  14. Detailed definitions of these variables are provided in Appendix E

  15. Many studies show that equity issuance has gradually become a major source of cash savings because of precautionary motives (DeAngelo et al. 2010; McLean 2011; Bolton et al. 2013; Eisfeldt and Muir 2016).

  16. Earnings-based covenants usually specify debt limits as a function of internal funds.

  17. See Appendix A.2 of Lian and Ma (2021) for details about the classification procedures.

  18. The original insight of using the payout ratio to measure financial constraints is built on the notion that the payout policy is a central liquidity management tool (Fazzari et al. 1988). Recent empirical analyses challenge this notion, nonetheless. Almeida et al. (2016), for example, show that stock repurchases are conducted not only to manage liquidity but also to manage earnings-per-share. In particular, the unprecedented increase in stock repurchases over the last 20 years suggests that payout behavior may no longer provide a helpful indicator of constraints (Farre-Mensa et al. 2014).

  19. These measures are obtained from Joel Hasbrouck’s Web site. They are available through 2006, so this reduces the number of observations when we use these measures.

  20. Almeida et al. (2021) reexamine the empirical evidence on the ACW model presented in Almeida et al. (2004) and also find the constraint measure based on the payout ratio yields weak support for the ACW model.

  21. Note that Almeida et al. (2004) focus only on manufacturing firms (SIC: 2000 to 3999). Table 15 shows that our results are robust after using the same filter.

  22. See Heider and Ljungqvist (2015) Appendix A for a list of the relevant tax increases.

  23. Given that tax shields can only benefit firms that have (or expect soon to have) profits to shield from tax, the debt test cannot be applied to chronically loss-making firms. Following Farre-Mensa and Ljungqvist (2016), we excludes firm-years with a zero marginal tax rate. Note that the marginal tax rates data are from Graham (1996a, 1996b). Missing values are filled in as recommended in Graham and Mills (2008).

  24. None of our corporate income tax increases coincides with a bank tax cut.

  25. There are four corporate tax increases that coincide with the lifting of bank branching restriction in the same state: MO (1990), MT (1990), NE (1990), and KS (1992). (See Kerr and Nanda (2009) for a complete list of deregulation events)

  26. In Warusawitharana and Whited (2015), the tax rate on dividends is 35%, and the linear cost is around 5%. Thus lower bound of overvaluation is approximately \(\frac{1}{(1-\tau _d)(1-a)}=160\%\).

  27. For example, Rhodes-Kropf et al. (2005), Hertzel and Li (2010), Fu et al. (2013).

  28. This dataset is available at WRDS website at https://wrds-www.wharton.upenn.edu/pages/get-data/peters-and-taylor-total-q/peters-and-taylor-total-q/.

  29. https://pages.stern.nyu.edu/jhasbrou/Research/GibbsEstimates2006/Liquidity%20estimates%202006.htm.

  30. Data can be found at Havard Dataverse at https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId doi:10.7910/DVN/T9KXMF/.

References

  • Acharya VV, Almeida H, Campello M (2007) Is cash negative debt? A hedging perspective on corporate financial policies. J Financ Intermediat 16:515–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida H, Campello M (2001) Financial constraints and investment-cash flow sensitivities: new research directions. In: Twelfth Annual Utah Winter Finance Conference

  • Almeida H, Campello M (2007) Financial constraints, asset tangibility, and corporate investment. Rev Financ Stud 20:1429–1460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida H, Campello M (2010) Financing frictions and the substitution between internal and external funds. J Financ Quant Anal 45:589–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida H, Campello M, Weisbach MS (2004) The cash flow sensitivity of cash. J Financ 59:1777–1804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida H, Campello M, Weisbach MS (2021) The cash flow sensitivity of cash: replication, extension, and robustness. Fisher College of Business Working Paper 002

  • Almeida H, Fos V, Kronlund M (2016) The real effects of share repurchases. J Financ Econ 119:168–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud Y (2002) Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series effects. J Financ Mark 5:31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Fairhurst D, Serfling M (2020) Employment protection, investment, and firm growth. Rev Financ Stud 33:644–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker M, Wurgler J (2002) Market timing and capital structure. J Financ 57:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bao D, Chan KC, Zhang W (2012) Asymmetric cash flow sensitivity of cash holdings. J Corp Finan 18:690–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates TW, Kahle KM, Stulz RM (2009) Why do us firms hold so much more cash than they used to? J Financ 64:1985–2021

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum CF, Schäfer D, Talavera O (2011) The impact of the financial system’s structure on firms’ financial constraints. J Int Money Financ 30:678–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger PG, Ofek E, Swary I (1996) Investor valuation of the abandonment option. J Financ Econ 42:259–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B, Gertler M, Gilchrist S (1996) The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. Rev Econ Stat. https://doi.org/10.3386/w4789

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodnaruk A, Loughran T, McDonald B (2015) Using 10-k text to gauge financial constraints. J Financ Quant Anal 50:623–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Chen H, Wang N (2011) A unified theory of Tobin’s q, corporate investment, financing, and risk management. J Financ 66:1545–1578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Chen H, Wang N (2013) Market timing, investment, and risk management. J Financ Econ 109:40–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campello M, Graham JR, Harvey CR (2010) The real effects of financial constraints: evidence from a financial crisis. J Financ Econ 97:470–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen HJ, Chen SJ (2012) Investment-cash flow sensitivity cannot be a good measure of financial constraints: evidence from the time series. J Financ Econ 103:393–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Q, Chen X, Schipper K, Xu Y, Xue J (2012) The sensitivity of corporate cash holdings to corporate governance. Rev Financ Stud. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhs099

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-S, Wang Y (2012) Financial constraints and share repurchases. J Financ Econ 105:311–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeAngelo H, DeAngelo L, Stulz RM (2010) Seasoned equity offerings, market timing, and the corporate lifecycle. J Financ Econ 95:275–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong M, Hirshleifer D, Richardson S, Teoh SH (2006) Does investor misvaluation drive the takeover market? J Financ 61:725–762

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duchin R (2010) Cash holdings and corporate diversification. J Financ 65:955–992

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duchin R, Ozbas O, Sensoy BA (2010) Costly external finance, corporate investment, and the subprime mortgage credit crisis. J Financ Econ 97:418–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckbo BE, Makaew T, Thorburn KS (2018) Are stock-financed takeovers opportunistic? J Financ Econ 128:443–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisfeldt AL, Muir T (2016) Aggregate external financing and savings waves. J Monet Econ 84:116–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erel I, Jang Y, Weisbach MS (2015) Do acquisitions relieve target firms’ financial constraints? J Financ 70:289–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erickson T, Jiang CH, Whited TM (2014) Minimum distance estimation of the errors-in-variables model using linear cumulant equations. J Econom 183:211–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erickson T, Whited TM (2012) Treating measurement error in tobin’s q. Rev Financ Stud 25:1286–1329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faccio M, ** X (2015) Taxes and capital structure. J Financ Quant Anal 50:277–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, MacBeth JD (1973) Risk, return and equilibrium: empirical tests. J Polit Econ 81:607–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farre-Mensa J, Ljungqvist A (2016) Do measures of financial constraints measure financial constraints? Rev Financ Stud 29:271–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farre-Mensa J, Michaely R, Schmalz M (2014) Payout policy. Annu Rev Financ Econ 6:75–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari SM, Glenn Hubbard R, Petersen BC, Blinder AS, Poterba JM (1988) Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brook Pap Econ Act 1988:141–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank MZ, Goyal VK (2009) Capital structure decisions: which factors are reliably important? Financ Manag 38:1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fu F, Lin L, Officer MS (2013) Acquisitions driven by stock overvaluation: are they good deals? J Financ Econ 109:24–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • González VM (2015) The financial crisis and corporate debt maturity: the role of banking structure. J Corp Finan 35:310–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR (1996) Debt and the marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 41:41–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR (1996) Proxies for the corporate marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 42:187–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Lemmon ML, Schallheim JS (1998) Debt, leases, taxes, and the endogeneity of corporate tax status. J Financ 53:131–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Mills L (2008) Simulating marginal tax rates using tax return data. J Account Econ 46:366–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gryglewicz S (2011) A theory of corporate financial decisions with liquidity and solvency concerns. J Financ Econ 99:365–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadlock CJ, Pierce JR (2010) New evidence on measuring financial constraints: moving beyond the kz index. Rev Financ Stud 23:1909–1940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck J (2009) Trading costs and returns for us equities: estimating effective costs from daily data. J Financ 64:1445–1477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heider F, Ljungqvist A (2015) As certain as debt and taxes: estimating the tax sensitivity of leverage from state tax changes. J Financ Econ 118:684–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy CA, Whited TM (2007) How costly is external financing? Evidence from a structural estimation. J Financ 62:1705–1745

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertzel MG, Li Z (2010) Behavioral and rational explanations of stock price performance around SEOs: evidence from a decomposition of market-to-book ratios. J Financ Quant Anal 45:935–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoberg G, Maksimovic V (2015) Redefining financial constraints: a text-based analysis. Rev Financ Stud 28:1312–1352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B, Tirole J (1997) Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Q J Econ 112:663–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovakimian G (2009) Determinants of investment cash flow sensitivity. Financ Manage 38:161–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itzkowitz J (2015) Buyers as stakeholders: how relationships affect suppliers’ financial constraints. J Corp Finan 31:54–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivashina V, Scharfstein D (2010) Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008. J Financ Econ 97:319–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • James C, Clodomiro F, Maren F, Paolo S (2023) Monetary policy, corporate finance, and investment. J Eur Econ Assoc. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvad009/7080145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayaratne J, Strahan PE (1996) The finance-growth nexus: evidence from bank branch deregulation. Q J Econ 111:639–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan Steven N, Luigi Zingales (1997) Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints? Q J Econ. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kayhan A, Titman S (2007) Firms’ histories and their capital structures. J Financ Econ 83:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemsley D, Nissim D (2002) Valuation of the debt tax shield. J Financ 57:2045–2073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr WR, Nanda R (2009) Democratizing entry: banking deregulations, financing constraints, and entrepreneurship. J Financ Econ 94:124–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khurana IK, Martin X, Pereira R (2006) Financial development and the cash flow sensitivity of cash. J Financ Quant Anal 41:787–808

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (1997) Credit cycles. J Polit Econ 105:211–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee CMC, Myers J, Swaminathan B (1999) What is the intrinsic value of the dow? J Financ 54:1693–1741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemmon ML, Zender JF (2010) Debt capacity and tests of capital structure theories. J Financ Quant Anal 45:1161–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lian C, Ma Y (2021) Anatomy of corporate borrowing constraints. Q J Econ 136:229–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLean RD (2011) Share issuance and cash savings. J Financ Econ 99:693–715

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meng Q, Li X, Chan KC, Gao S (2020) Does short selling affect a firm’s financial constraints? J Corp Finan 60:101531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minton BA, Schrand C (1999) The impact of cash flow volatility on discretionary investment and the costs of debt and equity financing. J Financ Econ 54:423–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB (1997) Scale economies, the value of time, and the demand for money: longitudinal evidence from firms. J Polit Econ 105:1061–1079

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers Stewart C (1984) Capital structure puzzle. NBER Working Paper

  • Opler T, Pinkowitz L, Stulz R, Williamson R (1999) The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings. J Financ Econ 52:3–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters RH, Taylor LA (2017) Intangible capital and the investment-q relation. J Financ Econ 123:251–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes-Kropf M, Robinson DT, Viswanathan S (2005) Valuation waves and merger activity: the empirical evidence. J Financ Econ 77:561–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riddick LA, Whited TM (2009) The corporate propensity to save. J Financ 64:1729–1766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roll R (1984) A simple implicit measure of the effective bid-ask spread in an efficient market. J Financ 39:1127–1139

    Google Scholar 

  • Santos JAC (2011) Bank corporate loan pricing following the subprime crisis. Rev Financ Stud 24:1916–1943

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shyam-Sunder L, Myers SC (1999) Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure. J Financ Econ 51:219–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smolyansky M (2019) Policy externalities and banking integration. J Financ Econ 132:118–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE, Weiss A (1981) Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. Am Econ Rev 71:393–410

    Google Scholar 

  • Sufi A (2009) Bank lines of credit in corporate finance: an empirical analysis. Rev Financ Stud 22:1057–1088

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (2010) The theory of corporate finance. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Warusawitharana M, Whited TM (2015) Equity market misvaluation, financing, and investment. Rev Financ Stud 29:603–654

    Google Scholar 

  • Whited TM, Guojun W (2006) Financial constraints risk. Rev Financ Stud 19:531–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • **ang H (2023) Time inconsistency and financial covenants. Manag Sci. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2022.4667

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

** Hu

  • Corresponding author

    Correspondence to **ao Zhang.

    Ethics declarations

    Conflict of interest

    The author declare that they have no conflict of interest.

    Additional information

    Publisher's Note

    Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

    Appendices

    A numerical example for the availability and cost constraints

    Following Tirole (2010), we consider an entrepreneur has a project. This project requires a fixed investment I, the initial asset is A, where \(A-I<0\). Thus, the firm must borrow. If the project succeeds, the return is \(R>0\). Otherwise, \(R=0\). The probability of success is denoted by p. The entrepreneur can behave or misbehave. The probability of success, \(p=p_H\) if the entrepreneur behaves while \(p=p_L\) if the entrepreneur misbehaves, and \(p_H>p_L\). If the entrepreneur misbehaves, he gets a private benefit G from misbehaving.

    Following Tirole (2010), we assume that borrowers and lenders are risk-neutral. There is no time preference (the discount rate is 0). The loan has zero profit. If the project fails, both the borrower and lender receive 0. If the project succeeds, the two parties share the return R; \(R_b\) goes to borrowers and \(R_l\) goes to the lender.

    1.1 Cost constraint

    The external financing is B,

    $$\begin{aligned} B=I-A \end{aligned}$$

    In the case of costly external financing, an increase in A reduces B. That is,

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial B}{\partial A}<0 \end{aligned}$$

    1.2 Availability constraint

    Next, we discuss the “availability constraint” through the borrowing capacity. To enable the borrower to behave, the incentive compatibility constraint is:

    $$\begin{aligned} p_HR_b\ge p_LR_b+G \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, the highest income that can be pledged to the lenders without jeopardizing the borrower’s incentives is \(R-\frac{G}{\Delta p}\), where \(\Delta p=(p_H-p_L)\).

    The pledgeable income is,

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {P}}=p_H \left(R-\frac{G}{\Delta p}\right) \ge I-A=B \end{aligned}$$

    In addition, the pledgeable income should exceed the lenders’ initial outlay. Then we have,

    $$\begin{aligned} A\ge I-p_H \left(R-\frac{G}{\Delta p}\right) \end{aligned}$$

    and, when \(I>0\),

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{I}{A}\le \frac{I}{I-p_H(R-G/\Delta p)}=k. \end{aligned}$$

    Since \(I>0\) and \(p_H(R-G/\Delta p)<I\), we have \(k>1\). The borrowing should satisfy the following condition,

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{I}{A}-1=\frac{B}{A}\le =k-1 \Rightarrow B\le (k-1)A. \end{aligned}$$

    The term \((k-1)A\) is the availability constraint. When a borrower faces availability constraints, the borrowing reaches the borrowing capacity. That is,

    $$\begin{aligned} B=(k-1)A \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, in the case of availability constraints, an increase in A increases B. That is

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial B}{\partial A}=(k-1)>0. \end{aligned}$$

    B Other stylized facts

    See Table 11.

    Table 11 Composition of financially constrained and unconstrained firm-years

    C Robustness tests

    See Tables 12, 13, 14 and 15.

    Table 12 Robustness: mismeasurement of Q corrected by High Order Cumulant estimator
    Table 13 Robustness: mismeasurement of Q corrected by the ‘total q’
    Table 14 Robustness: alternate classification cutoffs
    Table 15 Robustness: manufacturing firms (SICs 2000–3999)

    D Decomposition of market-to-book equity ratio

    A firm’s log market-to-book equity ratio can be decomposed into two items,

    $$\begin{aligned} ln(\frac{ME}{BE}) = ln(\frac{ME}{VE}) + ln(\frac{VE}{BE}) \end{aligned}$$

    Where ME is the observed market value of equity and BE is the book value of equity. VE represents the intrinsic value of equity, which is unobservable.

    To use this decomposition, we must estimate VE. The traditional method of calculating the intrinsic value is usually based on the residual income model (Lee et al. 1999; Dong et al. 2006). However, this model rests on a number of strict assumptions that make it difficult to distinguish between mispricing and growth components clearly. Rhodes-Kropf et al. (2005) relax the residual income model and assume that a firm’s intrinsic value can be expressed as a linear function of accounting variables, which include book equity (BE), net income (NI) and market leverage (MLEV) ratio. The regression is:

    $$\begin{aligned} ln(ME_{it})=\alpha _{0jt}+\alpha _{1jt}ln(BE_{it})+\alpha _{2jt}ln|NI|_{it}+\alpha _{3jt}I_{<0}ln|NI|_{it}+\alpha _{4jt}MLEV_{it}+\varepsilon _{it} \end{aligned}$$

    where, |NI| is the absolute value of net income. \(I_{<0}\) is a dummy variable that is equal to one if net income is negative. The subscript ijt stands for firm, industry and time, respectively. As shown above, the parameters are allowed to vary over time and across industries to reflect the variation in investment opportunities across times and industries. Specifically, each year we group firms according to the 12 Fama and French industry classification and run cross-sectional regressions for each industry to estimate the parameters \(\alpha _{jt}\). Like previous studies, the average adjusted \(R^2\) for these regressions exceed \(80 \%\) for almost all industries.Footnote 27 Following Rhodes-Kropf et al. (2005), we get industry-variant parameters \({\overline{\alpha }}_j\) by averaging the \(\alpha _{jt}\) from the annual regressions for each industry. Then the intrinsic value can be expressed as:

    $$\begin{aligned} ln(VE_{it})={\overline{\alpha }}_{0t}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{j}ln(BE_{it})+{\overline{\alpha }}_{2t}ln|NI|_{it}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{3t}I_{<0}ln|NI|_{it}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{4t}MLEV_{it} \end{aligned}$$

    As \(\varepsilon _{it}\) captures the deviation of intrinsic value from observed market value of equity, then \(ln(ME_{it})-ln(VE_{it})\) can be interpreted as the firm-level mispricing at a point of time. Intuitively, if markets know the future growth opportunities, discount rates, and cash flows, \(ln(ME_{it})-ln(VE_{it})\) should equal to zero. If markets make false predictions or do not have information that managers have, then \(ln(ME_{it})-ln(VE_{it})\) will capture the misvaluation component of the market to book equity ratio.

    Definitions of key variables

    Firm-level variables

    • Assets (AT) Book value of total assets (Compustat item at).

    • Capital (K) Net property, plant and equipment (Compustat item ppent).

    • Sales growth (SG) Annual percentage growth in sales (Compustat item sale). It is calculated as sale/l.sale - 1.

    • Market value (M) Market value of total assets (Compustat item prccf \(\times\) csho + at -txdb-ceq).

    • Market equity (ME) Market value of equity (Compustat item prccf\(\times\)csho).

    • Book equity (BE) Book value of equity (Compustat item ceq).

    • Cash holdings (CASH) Cash and cash equivalents (Compustat item che) scaled by total assets.

    • Cash savings (\(\Delta CASH\)) Changes in cash holdings.

    • Cash flow (CF) Firm’s cash flow in a year (Compustat item ib+dp-dvt) scaled by total assets.

    • Tobin’s q (Q) Market value divided by book value of total assets.

    • Total q (\(Q_{tot}\)) New Tobin’s q measure that accounts for intangible capital, provided by Peters and Taylor (2017).Footnote 28

    • EBITDA (EBITDA) Earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortization (Compustat item oibdp) scaled by total assets.

    • Net income (loss) (NI) Fiscal income or loss after subtracting expenses and losses from all revenues and gains (Compustat item ni) scaled by total assets.

    • Issuance costs (Cost) We mainly use three measures of issuance costs (Gibbs, Amihud, and Amivest) obtained from Joel Hasbrouck’s website.Footnote 29Gibbs is the Hasbrouck (2009) Bayesian estimate of the basic market-adjusted model adapted from Roll (1984). Amihud is the Amihud (2002) illiquidity measure, which is the absolute value of daily returns divided by daily dollar volume. Amivest is a liquidity measure, which is the amount of volume needed to get a unit change in stock price.

    • Net debt issuance (NDEBT) Net proceeds from debt sales (Compustat item dltis-dltr) scaled by total assets.

    • Net equity issuance (NEQUITY) Net proceeds from equity issues (Compustat item sstk-prstkc) scaled by total assets.

    • Cash flow-based lending (\(Lending^{CF-Based}\)) Cash flow-based lending scaled by total assets.Footnote 30

    • Investment (Investment) Capital expenditure (Compustat item capx) scaled by total assets.

    • R& D (\(R \& D\)) Research and development expense (Compustat item xrd) scaled by total assets.

    • Tangibility (Tangibility) Asset tangibility. It is constructed following Berger et al. (1996) and Almeida and Campello (2007) as 0.715 \(\times\) Receivables (Compustat item rect/at) + 0.547 \(\times\) Inventory (Compustat item invt/at) + 0.535 \(\times\) Capital (Compustat item ppent/at).

    • Long-term book leverage (LEV) Long-term debt (Compustat item dltt) scaled by total assets.

    • Fraction of fixed assets (FixAsset) The ratio of net fixed assets (Compustat item ppent) to total assets.

    • Market leverage (MLEV) Market leverage ratio, which is defined as 1-Market equity/Market value.

    • Cash flow volatility (CFVOL) Cash flow uncertainty proxy. It is constructed following Minton and Schrand (1999) as standard deviation of quarterly cash flow using sample over the previous 6-year period.

    • Mispricing component (Overvaluation) The ratio of market equity to intrinsic value, which is regarded as the mispricing component in market to boot equity ratio. The natural logarithm of the intrinsic value can be expressed as a linear function of observable accounting information, including net income, market leverage and book equity: \(ln(VE_{it})={\overline{\alpha }}_{0t}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{j}BE_{it}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{2t}ln|NI|_{it}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{3t}I_{<0}ln|NI|_{it}+{\overline{\alpha }}_{4t}MLEV_{it}\). We estimate the coefficients following Rhodes-Kropf et al. (2005).

    • Marginal tax rate (MTR) Following Graham et al. (1998), We use after-interest marginal tax rates (variable mtrafter) from John Graha (http://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/jgraham/taxform.html). Missing values are filled in as recommended in Graham and Mills (2008).

    • Firm-level cash flow sensitivity (\(F-CFSC\)) First, we get residuals \(\varepsilon _{it}\) by regressing cash savings on control variables, including Tobin’s q and size. Then, we define the firm-level cash flow sensitivity as the difference between cash flow weighted-average residuals and simple average residuals. The calculation mainly follow Hovakimian (2009).

    Financial constraint measures

    • Firm size (SIZE) Natural logarithm of the book value of total assets.

    • Payout ratio (DIV) The ratio of total distributions (Compustat item dvt+prstkc) to operating income (Compustat item oibdp).

    • HP index (HP) The variable measures financial constraints. The calculations follow Hadlock and Pierce (2010).

    • WW index (WW) The variable measures financial constraints. The calculations follow Whited and Wu (2006).

    Macro variables

    • Recession dummy (Recession) The recession dummy that is equal to one if six or more of the previous 12 months had declining GDP and zero otherwise.

    • Default spread (Spread) The difference between Moody’s seasoned Aaa and Baa corporate bond yields.

    Rights and permissions

    Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

    Reprints and permissions

    About this article

    Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

    Cite this article

    Hu, W., Zhang, X. & He, Y. Cash flow sensitivity of cash: when should we use it to measure financial constraints?. Rev Quant Finan Acc 62, 637–682 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-023-01219-3

    Download citation

    • Accepted:

    • Published:

    • Issue Date:

    • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-023-01219-3

    Keywords

    JEL Classification

    Navigation