Log in

‘Constructing a New Socialist Countryside’ and Beyond: An Analytical Framework for Studying Policy Implementation and Political Stability in Contemporary China

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Chinese Political Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article proposes a two-dimensional analytical framework to investigate the impact of local policy implementation on political system stability and legitimacy in China. It combines David Easton’s political systems theory with policy analysis and a variant of actor-centered institutionalism known as “strategic group analysis”. In the second part of the article, this framework is applied to a case study on local implementation of the official “constructing a new socialist countryside” policy in Qingyuan County, Zhejiang Province.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Germany)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although the incidence of social protest has been increasing in China during recent years, it still holds true, as Liz Perry and Marc Selden noted some time ago, that “for all the popular anguish and the variety and depth of contemporary protest, to date no significant organizational focus, whether enshrined in a political party or social movement, has emerged at the national, regional or even local level to challenge Communist Party leadership” ([57]: 16).

  2. The case study is part of a broader research project led by Gunter Schubert and Thomas Heberer (University of Duisburg-Essen) that analyzes local policy implementation and the political autonomy of county and township cadres in six rural counties, each located in one of the following provinces: Shaanxi, Zhejiang, Jiangxi, Shandong, Sichuan, and Guizhou. In this article, we present the case of Qingyuan County, Zhejiang province. In 2008 and 2009, we conducted some 25 interviews with government and party officials at the county, township and village levels (most of whom were interviewed twice), and also spoke with a number of peasants. There will be a new round of fieldwork in Qingyuan in September 2010; for more detailed information on Qingyuan county, see the appendix.

  3. Other systems belonging to this environment are, for instance, the economic, cultural, and ecological systems (the ‘intra-societal environment’), as well as the international political, economic, and social systems (‘the extra-societal environment’), see p. 23 in Easton [21].

  4. According to Easton, the feedback loop “consists of the production of outputs by the authorities, a response to these on the part of the members of society, the communication of information about this response to the authorities and finally, possible succeeding actions on the part of the authorities. By this means, a new round of outputs, response, information feedback and reaction on the part of the authorities is set in motion and is part of a continuous, never-ending flow” ([21]: 28–29).

  5. David Easton’s modeling of the political system has often been criticized as theoretically tautological (and even apologetic), because any system may be called stable and legitimate, that is, persistent, as long as it continues to operate (see e.g. Bang [4] for a review of this critique). However, we concentrate on the empirical application of the Eastonian model by linking it to policy analysis and testing it against the consequences of local policy implementation. Our interest in the model is thus foremost pragmatic.

  6. The suggestion that the Chinese political system is stable because it enjoys sufficient degrees of legitimacy is confirmed by much of the recent public opinion literature. See e.g. surveys of the Asian Barometer Project [3]; the World Values Survey [93]; the Pew Global Attitudes Project [59]; or studies featuring opinion polls or other surveys such as Chen [13]; Chen et al. [15]; Gilley [28]; Shi [72]; Tang [79]; Shi and Lou [73]; Walder [87]; some contributions in White [90]; Zhong [109]. For those further studies pointing at the success of China’s central government in adopting relevant policies and allowing for their adaptation to local demands during the implementation process, see e.g. Naughton and Yang [55].

  7. According to Easton, specific support “is directed towards the political authorities and authoritative institutions. It assumes that members have sufficient political awareness to be able to associate satisfaction and dissatisfaction with the perceived behaviour of these authorities, whether the behaviour is in the form of identifiable actions or some attributed general performance” ([22]: 439).

  8. We are aware that this point is contested. As one of our Chinese research assistants remarked, on one occasion, as we were discussing the future of China, system persistence cannot be connected to regime legitimacy in China, because most of the Chinese people, particularly younger generations, are just too disillusioned with the Communist Party and simply go along with its policies and actions, trying to make the best of things. If this is true, the acceptance or toleration of outputs would be dictated by pragmatism or indifference, not by moral consent. Nevertheless, there is no survey data available to further qualify these assumptions.

  9. The belief in legitimacy is one component of diffuse support in Easton’s model (the other being trust) and derives “from the conviction on the part of the member that it is right and proper for him to accept and obey the authorities and to abide by the requirements of the regime. It reflects the fact that in some vague or explicit way he sees these objects as conforming to his own moral principles, his own sense of what is right and proper in the political sphere” ([21]: 278). We are not specifically concerned with ‘trust’ in this article which, to our understanding, has not been convincingly clarified with respect to its conceptual relation to legitimacy in Easton’s major works.

  10. “Political authority is legitimate, we can say, to the extent that 1) it is acquired and exercised according to established rules (legality); 2) the rules are justifiable according to socially accepted beliefs about (a) the rightful source of authority, and (b) the proper ends and standards of government (normative justifiability); 3) positions of authority are confirmed by express consent or affirmation of appropriate subordinates, and by recognition from other legitimate authorities (legitimation)” ([7]: 110).

  11. At the same time, as Beetham argues, “actions can confer legitimacy without being based upon any ‘belief in legitimacy’. (...) Consent [can] be expressed entirely out of considerations of self-interest. It is the actions, involving implicit or explicit commitments that create a normative relationship, and reciprocal obligations, not any prior ‘belief in legitimacy’” ([5]: 42).

  12. It is important to note that for Beetham, overt or expressed consent such as electoral participation must be voluntary and visible, as “the view that people consent to power if they are not openly protesting against it is (...) quite inadequate” ([6]: 91).

  13. As a matter of fact, Easton’s model has strongly influenced policy analysis in the field of political science since the 1970s.

  14. Other authors identify fewer or more phases. See, for example, Jann and Wegrich [40]; Hill [37]: 18–27.

  15. Bounded rationality (or rationalism) as understood in this context pertains to the new institutionalism in the social sciences [58], which investigates the inter-relationship between agency and institutions (for China see Lieberthal [44]; Tsai [8385]) and also looks at feedback processes to analyze institutional stability and change ([60, 80]).

  16. Strategic groups as an analytical tool for exploring societal change and class formation processes have been an important focus of the ‘Bielefeld school’ of development sociology since the 1970s, producing much research on Southeast Asia and South Asia. The concept was later adapted to political science research on democratic transitions and finally applied by the China studies field to highlight the rise of private entrepreneurs in China’s market transformation; see, for example, Evers and Schiel [25]; Schubert et al. [70]; Heberer [33].

  17. Although peasants, migrants, private entrepreneurs, or social activists are also potential strategic groups, in our research, they paled in significance when compared to local cadres with regard to local policy implementation. However, this is an empirical issue that must be answered in relation to the specific policy investigated and the particular circumstances present in a locality. For the same reason, we did not integrated village cadres as a strategic group, as they lacked the power and influence to have a significant impact on policy implementation at our field sites.

  18. See among many others e.g. Chung [18]; Donaldson [20]; Fan et al. [26]; Guo [32]; Landry [42]; Smith [75]; Tsai [86]; Wu [98].

  19. This was also the topic in interviews with the vice party secretary of Qingyuan County on September 17, 2009 and with the mayors of two townships in Qingyuan County in September 2008 and 2009.

  20. Interview with members of the Lishui City Department of Rural Work, September 18, 2009.

  21. For a detailed description of local XNCJS policy formulation, implementation and, in particular, XNCJS project application procedure and funding, see for example, Ahlers and Schubert [1]; Li [43]; Su [77].

  22. Interview with the head of the Reform and Development Bureau, September 13, 2009.

  23. As the director of Qingyuan’s Reform and Development Bureau (fagaiju) explained, investments in the development of the countryside (zhinong) have increased to almost 90% of the county budget in 2009 (Interview on September 13, 2009). Other sources stated that XNCJS-related investments doubled from year to year, with the total share of higher-level transfers increasing around 15% annually. The budget of the XNCJS leading small group was CNY 50,000,000 in 2006 and 2007, of which the county itself allocated about CNY 20,000,000.

  24. This point has also been made by Thøgersen: “(...) The party secretary emphasized that only villages with well-connected leaders got money for projects” ([81]: 27).

  25. C.f. interviews with the party secretary of township A, September 19, 2008; and the government head of township B, September 23, 2008.

  26. The extent to which villagers actually participated in XNCJS-related policy formulation, even in the restricted sense mentioned, remained unclear to us; see also Ye [101].

  27. This increase may be partly due to the out-migration of workers and earnings in the non-agricultural sector. However, the encouragement of migration and the move toward wage labor is specifically integrated in Qingyuan’s XNCJS planning and thus does not necessarily diminish the success of the policy.

  28. Interviews with representatives of the Lishui City Department of Rural Works, September 18, 2009.

  29. Moreover, there is a regular horizontal and vertical evaluation of individual cadres with and without bianzhi and of the group of leading cadres (lingdao banzi: ‘political cadres’) at each level. Bianzhi usually refers to a certain number of official (or authorized) personnel within a unit, office, or organization and can be translated as “establishment” or “established posts”. To be a bianzhi cadre means to belong to a privileged hierarchy, enjoying special salary and allowance benefits and being entitled to move up to leading posts in the government or party apparatus. The core cadres of a certain administrative unit, such as a county government, form the lingdao banzi of that unit (see, for example, [9, 10: 79–82; 12, 41]). The lingdao banzi overlaps with the core of the stategic group of county and township cadres, but they are not identical.

  30. For each indicator there are fixed target values. The values shown here were collected from an evaluation sheet that Lishui City used to evaluate Qingyuan County’s XNCJS work; see Lishui City XNJCS Office [47].

  31. There is good reason to question the need of the county level to close ranks against the city or provincial authorities, as upper-level inspection tours and evaluation procedures are often communicated in advance to ensure that they go smoothly and to prevent any damage to political careers or reputations in the process. Our interviewees insisted, however, that evaluation is carried out “scientifically” and that no unofficial deals are made behind the scenes.

  32. Interview with the director of the Evaluation Bureau of Qingyuan County, September 12, 2009. See also Qingyuan County Evaluation Bureau [64].

  33. Interview, September 23, 2008. This rather flexible cooperation (or collusion) is a common feature and has been discovered and discussed by other scholars; see, for example, Zhou [110] or Zhao [107].

  34. The notion of “deep structure” to characterise the basic mode of operation of the Chinese political system, which still is hierarchical, was first used by Sebastian Heilmann and has been adopted in the present context.

  35. We asked peasants if they understood what XNJS meant, what it meant for them, what kind of measures had been implemented in their villages unter this heading, and what they thought about them. Our respondents clearly identified the new cooperative medical insurance system (hezuo yiliao) and the provision of basic allowances for the needy (wubao, dibao), in addition to road construction, as the most welcome government initiatives. However, we did not systematically interview villagers on these issues and thus only report our impressions.

  36. So far, we have not received the impression that villager participation via village assemblies or villager representative assemblies is very significant for XNCJS policy-making and implementation in Qingyuan, though we were told that each XNCJS project requires the consent of a majority of eligible voters in a process of democratic deliberation and decision-making. It seemed to us that mobilization by township cadres weighed stronger than bottom-up participation by peasants.

  37. For corresponding survey methods, see e.g. Chen and Zhong [14]; Chen [13]; Zhong [109].

References

  1. Ahlers, A.L., and G. Schubert. 2009. Building a new socialist countryside—Only a political slogan? Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 4: 35–62.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Appadurei, A. 1995. The production of locality. In Counterworks: Managing the diversity of knowledge, ed. R. Fardon, 204–225. London: Routledge.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  3. Asian Barometer Project. 2005–2008. https://www.asianbarometer.org (accessed on 20 June 2010).

  4. Bang, H.P. 1998. David Easton’s postmodern images. Political Theory 26(3): 281–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Beetham, D. 1991a. Max Weber and the legitimacy of the modern State. Analyse und Kritik 13(1): 34–45.

  6. Beetham, D. 1991b. The legitimation of power. Palgrave Macmillan: Houndmills.

  7. Beetham, D. 2001. Political legitimacy. In The Blackwell Companion to Political Sociology, ed. K. Nash and A. Scott, 107-116. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

  8. Brady, A-M. 2009. Mass persuasion as a means of legitimation and China’s popular authoritarianism. American Behavioral Scientist 53(3): 434-457.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Brødsgaard, K.E. 2002. Institutional reform and the Bianzhi system in China. The China Quarterly 170: 361–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Brødsgaard, K.E. 2009. Hainan. State, society, and business in a Chinese province. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Brødsgaard, K., and Y. Zheng 2006. The Chinese Communist Party in reform. London: Routledge.

  12. Burns, J.P. 2003. ‘Downsizing the Chinese state’. Government retrenchment in the 1990s. The China Quarterly 175: 775–802.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Chen, J. 2004. Popular political support in urban China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Chen, J. and Y. Zhong. 2002. Why do people vote in semicompetitive elections in China? The Journal of Politics 64: 178–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Chen, J., Y. Zhong, and J.W. Hillard. 1997. The level and sources of popular support for China’s current political regime. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 30(1): 45–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. China Daily. 2006. Your guide to ‘new socialist countryside’. http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/200603/08/eng20060308_248839.html (accessed on 16 November 2008).

  17. China.com. 2009. 2008 nian nongmin renjun chunshouru dadao 4761 yuan. bi 07 nian zeng 621 yuan [In 2008, Farmers’ per capita net income reached 4761 yuan, 621 yuan more than in 2007]. 2 February 2009, online: http://www.china.com.cn/news/2009-02/02/content_17209399.htm (accessed: March 20, 2009).

  18. Chung, J. H. 2000. Central control and local discretion in China. Leadership and implementation during Post-Mao decollectivization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Dickson, B. J., B. Gilley, M. Goldman and D.L. Yang. 2007. The future of China’s Party State. Current History September: 243–251.

  20. Donaldson, J.A. 2009. Why do similar areas adopt different developmental strategies? A study of two puzzling Chinese provinces. Journal of Contemporary China 18(60): 421–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Easton, D. 1967. A systems analysis of political life. New York: Wiley, 2nd edition.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Easton, D. 1975. A reassessment of the concept of political support. British Journal of Political Science 9: 435–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Edin, M. 2003. Remaking the communist party-state: The cadre responsibility system at the local level in China. China. An International Journal 1(1): 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Edin, M. 2003. State capacity and local agent control in China. CCP cadre management from a township perspective. The China Quarterly 173: 35–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Evers, H.-D., and T. Schiel (eds.). 1988. Strategische Gruppen. Vergleichende Studien zu Staat, Bürokratie und Klassenbildung in der Dritten Welt [Strategic groups. Comparative studies on state, bureaucracy and class formation in the thirld world]. Berlin: Dietrich Reimer.

  26. Fan, J., T. Heberer, and W. Taubmann. 2006. Rural China economic and social change in the late twentieth century. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Friedman, E. 2008. Why the dominant party in China won't loose. In Learning to lose. Political transitions in dominant party systems, ed. E. Friedman and J. Wong, 252-268. London: Routledge.

  28. Gilley, B. 2008. Legitimacy and institutional change. The case of China. Comparative Political Studies 41(3): 259–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Gilley, B. and H. Holbig. 2009. The debate on party legitimacy in China: a mixed quantitative/qualitative analysis. Journal of Contemporary China 18(59): 339–358.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Göbel, C. 2008. The peasant’s rescue from the cadre? An institutional analysis of China’s rural tax and fee reform. In Regime legitimacy in contemporary China. Institutional change and stability, ed. T. Heberer and G. Schubert, 35–54. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Gov.cn. 2006. Nongyebu jiang weirao ‘yicun yipin’ zhongdian fuchi yipi chanye fazhan [Ministry of agriculture will focus on ‘one village, one product’ to support industrial development]. 26 May 2006. http://www1.www.gov.cn/jrzg/2006-05/26/content_292075.htm (accessed on 20 August 2009).

  32. Guo, G. 2009. China’s local political budget cycles. American Journal of Political Science 53(3): 621–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Heberer, T. 2003. Strategic groups and state capacity: The case of the private entrepreneurs. China Perspectives 46: 4–14.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Heberer, T., and G. Schubert. 2006. Political reform and regime legitimacy in contemporary China. ASIEN 99: 9–28.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Heberer, T., and G. Schubert (eds.). 2009. Regime legitimacy in contemporary China. Institutional change and stability. London: Routledge.

  36. Heimer, M. 2006. The cadre responsibility system and the changing needs of the party. In The Chinese communist party in reform, ed. K.E. Brødsgaard and Y. Zheng, 122–138. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Hill, M. 1997. The policy process in the modern state. London: Prentice Hall/Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Holbig, H. 2009. Ideological reform and political legitimacy in China: Challenges in the Post-Jiang era. In Regime legitimacy in contemporary China: Institutional change and stability, ed. T. Heberer and G. Schubert, 13–34. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Holbig, H., and B. Gilley. 2010. In search of legitimacy in post-revolutionary China: Bringing ideology and governance back in. GIGA Working Paper 127, German Institute of Global and Area Studies, Hamburg. http://www.giga-hamburg.de/dl/download.php?d=/content/publikationen/pdf/wp127_holbig-gilley.pdf (accessed on 09 April 2010).

  40. Jann, W., and K. Wegrich. 2007. Theories of the policy cycle. In Handbook of public policy analysis: Theory, politics and methods, ed. F. Fischer, G.J. Miller, and M.S. Sidney, 43–62. London: CRC Press Taylor & Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Kim, J. 2005. An inquiry of the Bianzhi reform in Chinese politics. Review of International and Area Studies 14(2): 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Landry, P. 2008. Decentralized authoritarianism in China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  43. Li, Y. (ed.). 2007. Caizheng yu shehui zhuyi xinnongcun jianshe [Finance and the socialist construction of a new countryside]. Bei**g: Zhongguo caizheng **gji chubanshe [China Financial & Economic Publishing House].

  44. Lieberthal, K.G. 1992. The fragmented authoritarianism model and its limitations. In Bureaucracy, politics, and decision making in Post-Mao China, ed. K.G. Lieberthal and D.M. Lampton, 1–30. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Lin, Nan, and Zuohua Hu. 2006. Zhejiang ‘sheng guan xian’ yifa xinyilun zhidu tansuo [Zhejiang. ‘Sheng guan xian’ initiates new round of systemic questions]. http://news.xinhuanet.com/mrdx/2006-03/12/content_4293323.htm (accessed on 03 March 2009).

  46. Lingohr, S. 2007. Rural households, dragon heads and associations: A case study of sweet potato processing in Sichuan Province. The China Quarterly 192: 898–914.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Lishui City XNJCS Office. 2008. Guanyu yinfa lishui shi 2008 nian shehui zhuyi xinnongcun jianshe kaohe banfa ji gongzuo renwu de tongzhi [Circular on Lishui City XNJCS evaluation method and task assignment 2008] (internal document).

  48. Liu, **aopeng. 2008. ‘Sheng guan xian’ gaige xianlutu tuxian. Zhuanjia jianyi fen sanbu **xing [‘Sheng guan xian’ reform roadmap made clear. Experts suggest three steps of procedure]. http://news.xinhuanet.com/politics/2008-07/30/content_8845762.htm (accessed on 29 January 2009).

  49. Liu, M., J. Wang, R. Tao, and R. Murphy. 2009. The political economy of earmarked transfers in a state-designated poor county in Western China: Central policies and local responses. The China Quarterly 200: 973–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Ma, J.T. 2009. National economy: Steady and fast growth in 2008. http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/newsandcomingevents/t20090122_402534173.htm (accessed on 12 March 2009).

  51. Ministry of Finance. 2007. Report on China’s central and local budgets. Report on the implementation of the central and local budgets for 2006 and on the draft central and local budgets for 2007. http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/china/2007-03/19/content_830798.htm (accessed on 30 November 2008).

  52. Ministry of Finance. 2008. Report on China’s central and local budgets. Report on the implementation of the central and local budgets for 2007 and on the draft central and local budgets for 2008. http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/2008-03/20/content_7826586.htm (accessed on 30 November 2008).

  53. Ministry of Finance. 2009. Report on China’s central and local budgets. Report on the implementation of the central and local budgets for 2008 and on the draft central and local budgets for 2009. http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/2009-03/15/content_11013054.htm (accessed on 10 January 2010).

  54. Nathan, A.J. 2003. Authoritarian resilience. Journal of Democracy 14(1): 6–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. Naughton, B.J., and D.L. Yang. 2004. Holding China together. Diversity and national integration in the Post-Deng-Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  56. O’Brien, K., and L. Li. 1999. Selective policy implementation in rural China. Comparative Politics 31(2): 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Perry, E.J., and M. Selden. 2002. Chinese society: Change, conflict, and resistance. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Peters, B.G. 1999. Institutional theory in political science. The ‘new institutionalism’. London: Continuum.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Pew Global Attitudes Project. 2008. Some positive signs for U.S. image global economic gloom—China and India notable exeptions. 24-Nation pew global attitudes survey. http://pewglobal.org/files/pdf/260.pdf (accessed on 20 July 2010).

  60. Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in time. History, institutions, and social analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Qingwei [Qingyuan County Party Committee and Government]. 2006. Tui** shehui zhuyi xinnongcun jianshe ‘528’ xingdong jihua [The ‘528’ action plan to promote the building of a new socialist countryside]. Document No. 23.

  62. Qingwei [Qingyuan County Party Committee and Government]. 2009. Guanyu jiakuai tui** nongcun gaige fazhan de shixian yijian [Suggestions for accelerating the implementation of rural reform and development]. Document No. 14.

  63. Qingyuan Bureau of Finance. 2009. Qingyuanxian caizheng shouzhi yusuan zhixing qingkuangbiao 2008 nian 12 yue [Fact sheet on the budgetary setup of financial revenue and expenditure in Qingyuan County, December 2008], internal document.

  64. Qingyuan County Evaluation Bureau. 2008. 2008 niandu mubiao guanli zerenzhi kaohe jieguo yilanbiao. xianji jiguan [Result list of the 2008 target evaluation on county level]. Internal Document.

  65. Qingyuan County Government. 2003–2009. Zhengfu gongzuo baogao [Qingyuan county government work report]. http://www.zjqy.gov.cn/qyzw/zfgzbg/ (accessed on 20 June 2010).

  66. Qingyuan County Organization Department. 2006. Qingyuanxian **engxing xiangzhen zhengfu jianshe [Construction of skilled township governments in Qingyuan County]. Internal document.

  67. Scharpf, F.W. 1997. Games real actors play: Actor-centered institutionalism in policy research. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Schneider, V., and F. Janning. 2006. Politikfeldanalyse. Akteure, Diskurse und Netzwerke in der öffentlichen Politik [Policy analysis. Actors, discourses and networks in public policy]. Wiesbaden: VS-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Schubert, G. 2008. One-party rule and the question of legitimacy in contemporary China: Preliminary thoughts of setting up a new research agenda. Journal of Contemporary China 17(54): 191–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  70. Schubert, G., R. Tetzlaff, and W. Vennewald (eds.). 1994. Demokratisierung und Politischer Wandel. Theorie und Anwendung des Konzeptes der strategischen und konfliktfähigen Gruppen [Democratization and political change. Theory and application of the concept of strategic and conflict-capable groups]. Münster: LIT.

  71. Shambaugh, D. 2008. China’s communist party. Atrophy and adaptation. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  72. Shi, T. 1997. Political participation in Bei**g. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Shi, T., and D. Lou. 2010. Subjective evaluation of changes in civil liberties and political rights in China. Journal of Contemporary China 19(63): 175–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  74. Shue, V. 2004. Legitimacy crisis in China? In State and society in 21st century China: Crisis, contention, and legitimation, ed. P.H. Gries and S. Rosen, 24–49. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Smith, G. 2009. Political machinations in a rural county. The China Journal 62(2): 29–59.

    Google Scholar 

  76. State Council. 2006. Quanmian zhengque lijie shehui zhuyi xinnongcun jianshe [Fully and correctly understand the construction of a new socialist countryside]. http://www.gov.cn/node_11140/2006-03/15/content_227640.htm (accessed on 23 November 2008).

  77. Su, Minzi. 2009. China’s rural development policy. Exploring the ‘new socialist countryside’. Boulder: First Forum Press.

    Google Scholar 

  78. Su, F., and D. Yang. 2005. Elections, governance, and accountability in rural China. Asian Perspective 29(4): 125–157.

    Google Scholar 

  79. Tang, W. 2005. Public opinion and political change in China. Stanford: Standford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  80. Thelen, K. 2004. How institutions evolve. The political economy of skills in Germany, Britain, Japan and the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  81. Thøgersen, S. 2009. Revisiting a dramatic triangle: The state, villagers, and social activists in Chinese rural reconstruction projects. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 38(4): 9–33.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Tian, J.Q. 2009. Reorganizing rural public finance: Reforms and consequences. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 38(4): 145–171.

    Google Scholar 

  83. Tsai, K.S. 2002. Back-alley banking: Private entrepreneurs in China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  84. Tsai, K.S. 2006. Adaptive informal institutions and endogenous institutional change in China. World Politics 59: 116–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  85. Tsai, K.S. 2007. Capitalism without democracy. The private sector in contemporary China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  86. Tsai, L.L. 2007. Accountability without democracy. Solidarity groups and public goods provision in rural China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  87. Walder, A.G. 2009. Unruly stability: Why China’s regime has staying power. Current History 108(719): 257–263.

    Google Scholar 

  88. Wang, T. 2008. Jiejue xinnongcun jianshe zi** quekou zhi shexiang [Tentative plans to tackle the funds’ gap for the building of a new countryside]. http://theory.people.com.cn/GB/49154/49369/8422886.html (accessed on 20 December 2008).

  89. Wang, S. 2009. Changing models of China’s policy agenda setting. Modern China 34(1): 56–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  90. White, L.T. (ed.). 2005. Legitimacy. Ambiguities of political success or failure in East and Southeast Asia. New Jersey: World Scientific.

  91. Whiting, S.H. 2004. The cadre evaluation system at the grassroots: The paradox of party rule. In Holding China together, ed. B. Naughton and D.L. Yang, 101–119. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  92. Wong, C., and R. Bird. 2008. China’s fiscal system: A work in progress. In China’s great transformation: Origins, mechanism, and consequences of the post-reform economic boom, ed. L. Brandt and T. Rawski, 429–466. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  93. World Values Survey. 2005–2008: https://www.worldvaluessurvey.org (accessed on 20 June).

  94. Wu, Y. 2007. **aozhen xuanxiao. Yi ge xiangzhen zhengzhi yunzuo de yanyi yu chanshi [Noisy town. Interpretation and explanation of a township’s politics]. Bei**g: Sanlian shudian [SDX Joint Publishing Company].

    Google Scholar 

  95. **annongban [County Bureau of Rural Work]. 2006. Woxian jiancheng quansheng zuida de xiashan tuopin nongmin xincun [Our county builds the province’s largest new village for ‘peasants descending from the mountains to escape poverty’]. In Qingyuanxian xinnongcun jianshe dashiji [Memorabilia of XNCJS in Qingyuan County].

  96. **e, Y. 2007. Party adaptation and the prospects for democratization in authoritarian China. Issues & Studies 44(2): 79–102.

    Google Scholar 

  97. **nhua. 2008. CPC solicits rural reform opinions. Bei**g Review.com. http://www.bjreview.com.cn/special/third_plenum_17thcpc/txt/2008-10/14/content_156719.htm (accessed on 01 November 2008).

  98. **. http://news.xinhuanet.com/newscenter/2008-02/23/content_7655336.htm (accessed 15 March 2010).

  99. Yam, T.K. 2007. China’s 11th five-year plan: A critical perspective. In China’s surging economy. Adjusting for a more balanced development, ed. J. Wong and W. Liu, 55–132. New Jersey: World Scientific.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  100. Yang, D. 2004. Remaking the Chinese Leviathan. Market transition and the politics of governance in China. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  101. Ye, J.Z. (ed.). 2006. Nongmin shijiao de xinnongcun jianshe—Construction of the new countryside: Farmers’ perspectives. Bei**g: Shehui kexue wenxian chubanshe [Social Sciences Academic Press].

  102. Yu, K. 2009. Democracy is a good thing. Essays on politics, society, and culture in contemporary China. Washington: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  103. Yu, J.X., S.Z. Wang, and X. Gao. 2008. Qianfada diqu de xinnongcun jianshe. Yu zhonggong zhejiangsheng qingyuan xianwei shuji cao xiahua de duihua [Building a new countryside in underdeveloped areas. Dialogue with the county party secretary of Qingyuan County in Zhejiang Province, Cai **aohua]. Zhongguo Dangzheng Ganbu Luntan [China Party Cadre Forum]. http://www.dzlt.com/xknews/ONEWS.asp?id=673 (accessed on 02 September 2008).

  104. Zhang, Q.F., and J.A. Donaldson. 2008. The rise of agrarian capitalism with Chinese characteristics: Agricultural modernization, agribusiness and collective land rights. The China Journal 60: 25–47.

    Google Scholar 

  105. Zhang, Q.F., Q.G. Ma, and X. Xu. 2004. Development of land rental markets in rural Zhejiang: Growth of off-farm jobs and institution building. The China Quarterly 180: 1031–1049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  106. Zhao, S. 2006. Obligatory interactions in the affairs of township governments. Chinese Sociology and Anthropology 39(2): 17–25.

    Google Scholar 

  107. Zhao, S. 2006. The accountability system of township governments. Chinese Sociology and Anthropology 39(2): 64–73.

    Google Scholar 

  108. Zhejiang Party School. n/a. Qingyuan moshi yinqi quanguo guanzhu [‘Qingyuan Model’ attracts nation-wide attention]. http://kyw.zjdx.gov.cn/wcm/online/1166507890125_1166691518906_1166691658609.3/?pageno=22 (accessed on 02 August 2009).

  109. Zhong, Y. 2005. Democratic values among Chinese peasantry: An empirical study. China: An International Journal 3(2): 189–211.

    Google Scholar 

  110. Zhou, X. 2010. The institutional logic of collusion among local governance in China. Modern China 36(1): 47–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  111. Zhu, L.S. 2008. Fuwuxing xiangzhen zhengfu jianshe de shiran tansuo. Jiyu zhejiangsheng qingyuanxian **engxing zhengfu jianshe gean yanjiu [Exploring the construction of service-oriented township governments. A case study of the build-up of skilled government in Qingyuan County, Zhejiang Province]. Yunnan **ngzheng Xueyuan Xuebao [The Journal of Yunnan Administration College] 10(6):n/a.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We like to thank Björn Alpermann, Christian Göbel, Thomas Heberer and René Trappel for their comments on earlier drafts of this article, and three anonymous reviewers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gunter Schubert.

Appendix

Appendix

Qingyuan is the southernmost county of Zhejiang Province bordering Fujian and lies within the jurisdiction of the prefecture-level city of Lishui. It has a population of approximately 202,400 inhabitants, residing in the twenty townships and 345 villages under its administration. In 2009, the average annual per capita income amounted to CNY 5,278, whereas the national average for the same year was CNY 5,153 and CNY 10,007 for Zhejiang according to official figures. In 2009, Qingyuan’s total GDP was CNY 2,595 billion and per capita GDP of CNY 15,240, considerably less than the average per capita GDP of CNY 44,335 in Zhejiang Province. This is largely due to the county’s relative remoteness and still underdeveloped infrastructure. 53,000 people are employed in the agricultural sector and almost 90% of Qingyuan’s population hold a rural household registration. The main agricultural products are mushrooms, bamboo, rice, and mountain vegetables, as well as tea and tobacco on a smaller scale. The “shitake” or “fragrant mushroom” (xianggu) industry is the most important economic factor in the county; these mushrooms supply the Chinese market and are also exported on a large scale. Another important sector is the extensive bamboo growing and processing industry, which has led to Qingyuan’s becoming the largest production base for chopsticks in China. Lacking big industries, Qingyuan’s ecological environment has remained largely clean and intact, which resulted in Qingyuan being awarded several times the status of “China’s No. 1 eco-environment county” (zhongguo shengtai huan**g diyixian) in 2004 and “national ecological emulation county” (guojia shengtai shifanqu) in 2005. Qingyuan is also a popular destination for weekend tourists because of its (relatively) untouched nature and its historic “corridor bridges” (langqiao). Policy-making in Qingyuan is strongly conditioned by a specific feature of the administrative hierarchy in Zhejiang Province called “the province administers the county” (sheng guan xian), which affects the macro-level funding process and the domain of policy formulation and implementation. It places the county under the direct financial supervision of the provincial government, minimizing the city’s authority over the county level. This setup is supposed to reduce transaction costs and encourage county-level development (see, for example, [45, 48]).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schubert, G., Ahlers, A.L. ‘Constructing a New Socialist Countryside’ and Beyond: An Analytical Framework for Studying Policy Implementation and Political Stability in Contemporary China. J OF CHIN POLIT SCI 16, 19–46 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11366-010-9139-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11366-010-9139-6

Keywords

Navigation