Log in

The Cost of Unemployment from a Social Welfare Approach: The Case of Spain and Its Regions

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper proposes a protocol to measure the cost of unemployment by taking into account three different aspects: incidence, severity and hysteresis. Incidence refers to the conventional unemployment rate; severity takes into account both unemployment duration and the associated income loss; and hysteresis refers to the probability of remaining unemployed. The cost of unemployment is regarded as a welfare loss, which is measured by a utilitarian social welfare function whose arguments are the individual disutilities of unemployed workers. Each individual disutility is modelled as a function of income loss, unemployment duration and hysteresis. The resulting formula is simple and easy to understand and implement. We apply this assessment protocol to the Spanish labour market, focusing on the regional differences and using the official register of unemployed workers compiled by the Public Employment Service.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is some parallelism with the paper by Jones and Klenow (2016) in the use of a micro approach to address the problem and a multidimensional indicator that goes beyond the unemployment rate (beyond the GDP in their case).

  2. See Winter-Ebmer (2016) and de la Rica and Gorjón (2017) for a discussion. Recall that the United Nations have for many years been using the rate of long-term unemployment as a proxy for (lack of) social inclusion.

  3. According to the ILO definition, a person is unemployed if (1) he/she does not have a job, (2) is actively looking for a job, and (3) is available to start a new job in at most 15 days. Being registered in the Public Employment Services is not a necessary condition to be classified as unemployed by the ILO standards. Some unemployed, particularly if they have exhausted unemployment benefits, may not have incentives to register/renew their condition of unemployed in the SPES and so they would not appear in our database. Hence, to the extent that the total pool of unemployed workers by ILO standards is larger than the pool of workers registered in the SPES as unemployed, we are infra valuating the size of the pool of unemployed workers. Let us stress, however, that those differences have little impact on regional comparisons because of the symmetry of such disparities.

  4. We have run robustness checks changing the selected month and the patterns are barely the same.

  5. Following the recommendation of López-Labordaa et al. (2017), we use a Generalized Linear Model to estimate the predicted wage in order to avoid bias in the estimation results due to the retransformation problem from logarithms to wage levels.

  6. The monthly unemployment benefit is calculated as 70% of the monthly wage for the first 180 days and 50% of the monthly wage for the following months in which it is received. It is upper and lower bounded at €1411.83 and €501.98, respectively. The amount corresponding to social subsidies is 75%, 80% or 107% of the Multiple Effects Public Income Indicator (set at €532,51) depending on the type.

  7. As mentioned before, those figures are often lower than the conventional unemployment rates measured via the standard survey (Encuesta de Población Activa, in Spain). The difference for the whole country is some five points, up from 18.17 to 23.78%, and the coefficient of correlation between the two series is 0.8.

  8. It is worth mentioning that the choice of coefficient 2 in Goerlich and Miñano (2018) is practically the same as that obtained from using the probability of remaining unemployed.

  9. Note that, simple as it is, this model mimics what is a standard behaviour: the 16 h available in each working day (24 minus 8 devoted to rest) are equally split into 8 h of work and 8 hours of leisure.

  10. Needless to say, this function depends on the units in which wages and unemployment duration are measured.

  11. This parameter corresponds to the Arrow–Pratt coefficient of relative risk aversion for concave functions (e.g. Pratt 2013). This is the format adopted by Atkinson (1970) for his reference welfare function, by letting \(\varepsilon = - \nu\).

References

  • Atkinson, A. B. (1970). On the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory,2(3), 244–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barr, A., Miller, L., & Ubeda, P. (2016). Moral consequences of becoming unemployed. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences,113(17), 4676–4681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentolila, S., García-Pérez, J. I., & Jansen, M. (2017). Are the Spanish long-term unemployed unemployable? SERIEs,8(1), 1–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty, S. R. (2009). Inequality, polarization and poverty. Advances in distributional analysis. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, H. (1920). The measurement of the inequality of incomes. The Economic Journal,30(119), 348–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de La Rica, S., & Gorjón, L. (2017). Assessing the impact of a minimum income scheme in the Basque Country. New York: mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goerlich, F. J., & Miñano, A. (2018). Unemployment, spell duration and the burden of unemployment in Spain during the XXI Century, University of Valencia. New York: mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. I., & Klenow, P. J. (2016). Beyond GDP? Welfare across countries and time. American Economic Review,106(9), 2426–2457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-Labordaa, J., Marín-Gonzálezb, C., & Onrubiac, J. (2017). Estimating Engel curves: A new way to improve the SILC-HBS matching process. Documento de Trabajo, 15.

  • Pratt, J. W. (2013). Risk aversion in the small and in the large. In L. C. MacLean & W. T. Ziemba (Eds.), Handbook of the fundamentals of financial decision making: Part I (pp. 317–331). Singapore: World Scientific.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A., & Foster, J. E. (1973). On economic inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, M. (2009). Unemployment duration and the measurement of unemployment. The Journal of Economic Inequality,7(3), 273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks, A. (2009a). On the measurement of unemployment. The Journal of Economic Inequality,7(3), 311–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks, A. (2009b). Spell incidence, spell duration and the measurement of unemployment. The Journal of Economic Inequality,7(3), 295–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villar, A. (2017). Lectures on inequality, poverty and welfare. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Winter-Ebmer, R. (2016). Long-term effects of unemployment: What can we learn from plant-closure studies?, Chapter 4. In S. Bentolila & M. Janses (Eds.), Long-term unemployment after the great recession. Causes and Remedies. CEPR Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Antonio Villar.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The Formal Model

Consider the following extremely simple model of a worker whose utility depends on income and leisure according to the symmetric Cobb–Douglas function given by:

$$u\left( {y,L} \right) = ay^{1/2} L^{1/2}$$

where y stands for income, L for leisure, and a is a coefficient that defines the units in which utility is measured. Let T stand for the total amount of time available in a given period to be allocated between labour and leisure and let w denote the corresponding wage rate. Then, y = w(T − L), which results in:

$$u\left( {y,L} \right) = a\left[ {w(T - L)} \right]^{1/2} L^{1/2}$$

The consumer’s optimal choice consists of working for half of the available time and devoting the remaining half to leisure.Footnote 9 That is, y* = wT/2, L* = T/2, so that: u* = u(y*, L*) = aw1/2(T/2). By letting a = 2/T the following emerges:

$$u^{*} \, = u\left( {y^{*},L^{*}} \right) \, = w^{1/2}$$

That is, utility in equilibrium can be approximated by the square root of the market wage. When a worker h is unemployed he/she may receive: (a) an unemployment benefit sh per period (typically for a maximum of q* periods provided he/she has earned the pertinent rights); or (b) a social subsidy zh > 0, or nothing, zh = 0, per period. Therefore, we will have:

$$u_{h}^{0} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\left( {s_{h} } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill & {ifunemployment\;benefit} \hfill \\ {\left( {z_{h} } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill & {otherwise} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$

We can now define the average utility loss of a worker h unemployed for qh periods as the following cost function:

$$c_{h} (.) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\left( {w_{h} } \right)^{1/2} - \left( {s_{h} } \right)^{1/2} ,} \hfill & {if\;q_{h} \le q*} \hfill \\ {\frac{{\left( {w_{h} } \right)^{1/2} q_{h} - \left( {s_{h} } \right)^{1/2} q* - \left( {z_{h} } \right)^{1/2} \left( {q_{h} - q*} \right)}}{{q_{h} }}} \hfill & {if\;q_{h} > q*} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right\}} \hfill & {with\;unemp.\;benefits} \hfill \\ {\left( {w_{h} } \right)^{1/2} - \left( {z_{h} } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill & {with\;no\;unemployment\;benefits} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$

That is, the average disutility per period is measured by a cost function that reflects the impact on the agent’s utility of the corresponding income loss with respect to being employed. When the unemployed worker is entitled to unemployment benefits, the average utility loss is simply the square root of the lost wage minus the square root of the unemployment benefit. The worker may not be receiving those benefits either because was never entitled to them or because the unemployment spell exceeds the critical value q* (2 years in the case of Spain). In the first case the average utility corresponds to the difference of the square root of the lost wage and the square root of the social subsidy, if any. In the second case the average is slightly more involved because one has to compute the utility loss when receiving unemployment benefits for part of the time and social subsidies, if any, for the remaining time.Footnote 10

The simplest way of obtaining an overall measure of disutility for a worker h unemployed for qh months would be multiplying the average disutility per period by the number of periods. Yet it is sensible to think of duration entering disutility as an increasing and convex function, f(qh), as an extra month of unemployment is worse the longer the unemployment spell. Recall on this point that the degree of convexity of a function is related to its curvature, which is controlled by its second derivative, usually expressed in terms of the elasticity of the first derivative. In our case that elasticity measures the relative change in the marginal impact of duration on the relative change of individual unemployment length. The simplest constraint to control for the degree of convexity in this context is to assume constant elasticity. This makes it possible to parameterize the impact of unemployment duration by a single number: the value of the elasticity of marginal impact of duration, ν. The function that performs this task is well known and can be expressed as \(f\left( {q_{h} } \right) = q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }}\), where \(\nu_{h}\) stands for the elasticity of the marginal impact of duration for agent h.Footnote 11 This gives the following formula for the aggregate disutiluty of an agent:

$$d_{h} = c_{h} (.)q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }}$$

The overall per capita disutility can thus be expressed as:

$$D_{N} = \frac{1}{n}\sum\limits_{{h \in U_{N} }} {c_{h} (.)q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }} = \frac{{n^{U} }}{n} \times \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{{h \in U_{n} }} {c_{h} (.)q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }} } }}{{n^{U} }}}$$

This equation can be decomposed multiplicatively into three different components, along the lines in Shorrocks (2009b). To so let:

$$C^{U} = \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{{h \in U_{N} }} {c_{h} ( \cdot )} }}{{n^{U} }}, \ldots q_{N} = \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{{h \in U_{N} }} {q_{h} } }}{{n^{U} }}$$

denote the average income loss of the unemployed and the average duration of unemployment in society, respectively, and let \(\nu_{N}\) the average probability or remaining unemployed. Now consider the following elementary rewriting of DN:

$$D_{N} = \frac{{n^{U} }}{n} \times C^{U} q_{N}^{{1 + \nu_{N} }} \times \frac{1}{{n^{U} }}\sum\limits_{{h \in U_{N} }} {\frac{{c_{h} (.)q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }} }}{{C^{U} q_{N}^{{1 + \nu_{N} }} }}}$$

The first component of this expression corresponds to the incidence of unemployment (the head count ratio, HN). The second term, \(C^{U} q_{N}^{{1 + \nu_{N} }}\), is a measure of the intensity of unemployment, SN, given by the average disutility of the unemployed. Finally, the third term is a measure of inequality in disutility among the unemployed, IN, which is given by the sum of the shares of individual disutility in average disutility: To get an inequality measure that yields a zero value when all disutilities are equal, we take the following:

$$I_{N} = \frac{1}{{n^{U} }}\sum\limits_{{h \in U_{N} }} {\frac{{c_{h} ( \cdot )q_{h}^{{1 + \nu_{h} }} }}{{C^{U} q_{N}^{{1 + \nu_{N} }} }}} - 1$$

Appendix 2: Estimation Results

See Table 4.

Table 4 Probability of finding a job (1 − v)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gorjón, L., de la Rica, S. & Villar, A. The Cost of Unemployment from a Social Welfare Approach: The Case of Spain and Its Regions. Soc Indic Res 150, 955–976 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02360-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02360-5

Keywords

Navigation