Log in

High-growth firms and innovation: an empirical analysis for Spanish firms

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses the effect of R&D investment on firm growth. We use an extensive sample of Spanish manufacturing and service firms. The database comprises diverse waves of Spanish Community Innovation Survey and covers the period 2004–2008. First, a probit model corrected for sample selection analyses the role of innovation on the probability of being a high-growth firm (HGF). Second, a quantile regression technique is applied to explore the determinants of firm growth. Our database shows that a small number of firms experience fast growth rates in terms of sales or employees. Our results reveal that R&D investments positively affect the probability of becoming a HGF. However, differences appear between manufacturing and service firms. Finally, when we study the impact of R&D investment on firm growth, quantile estimations show that internal R&D presents a significant positive impact for the upper quantiles, while external R&D shows a significant positive impact up to the median.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Germany)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, see European Commission (2011).

  2. This study only considers incumbent firms since exiters are excluded. Here, we only consider organic growth, also called internal growth, which occurs when the firm grows from its own business activity.

  3. Initially, Hart and Oulton (1996) and Singh and Whittington (1968) found evidence that smaller firms grew faster than their larger counterparts, and Wagner (1992) found that those firms that grew faster in one period of time were more likely to grow faster in subsequent periods.

  4. Authors have used different periods of observation. For instance, Henrekson and Johansson (2010) consider HGFs to be those that grow more than 20 % every year for a period of 3 or 4 years, while Fritsch and Weyh (2006) used the longest period of 18 years.

  5. Daunfeldt et al. (2010) present an exhaustive panel of growth indicators and growth measurements used in empirical literature. They define HGFs by employment and sales and add definitions of added value and productivity.

  6. Recently the OECD and Eurostat in the Manual on Business Demography Statistics, European Communities/OECD 2008, define HGFs as: “All enterprises with average annualised growth in employees (turnover) greater than 20 % a year, over a 3-year period, and with 10 employees at the beginning of the observation period”. Note that the provisional size threshold of ten or more employees holds for both the turnover and employment measures. The advantage of this is that the initial population is the same, regardless of whether growth is measured in employment or turnover. Moreover, it would be difficult to apply a consistent turnover threshold across all countries participating in the data collection.

  7. Also in the Annex, there are graph quantiles of the marginal effects of the internal and external R&D effort on growth (see Graph A-1).

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Mueller, P. (2008). Employment effects of business dynamics: Mice, gazelles and elephants. Small Business Economics, 30, 85–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z., Parsons, W., Tracy, S. (2008). High-impact firms: Gazelles revisited. United States. Small Business Administration. Office of Advocacy. No. 328.

  • Almus, M. (2002). What characterizes a fast-growing firm? Applied Economics, 34(12), 1497–1508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1995). Innovation and industry evolution. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D., Menkveld, A., & Thurik, R. (1996). The decision between internal and external R&D. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 152, 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E. (1994). Towards an integrated Europe. London: CEPR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman, E., Scarpetta, S., & Schivardi, F. (2005). Comparative analysis of firm demographics and survival: evidence from micro-level sources in OECD countries. Industrial and Corporate Change, 14(3), 365–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basant, R., & Fikkert, B. (1996). The effects of R&D, foreign technology purchase, and domestic and international spillovers on productivity in Indian firms. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 187–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beneito, P. (2006). The innovative performance of in-house and contracted R&D in terms of patents and utility models. Research Policy, 35(4), 502–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birch, D. L. (1979). The job generation process. Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

  • Birch, D. L. (1981). Who creates jobs? The Public Interest, 65, 3–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B., & Taylor, C. (2000). R&D intensity and acquisitions in high-technology industries: Evidence from the US electronic and electrical equipment industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 47–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bönte, W. (2003). R&D and productivity: Internal vs. external R&D-evidence from West German manufacturing industries. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 12(4), 343–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braunerhjelm, P., Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Carlsson, B. (2010). The missing link: Knowledge diffusion and entrepreneurship in endogenous growth. Small Business Economics, 34(2), 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cainelli, G., Evangelista, R., & Savona, M. (2006). Innovation and economic performance in services: A firm-level analysis. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30(3), 435–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Catozzella, A., Vivarelli, M. (2007). The catalysing role of in-house R&D in fostering the complementarity of innovative inputs, IZA discussion papers 3126, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

  • Cefis, E., & Orsenigo, L. (2001). The persistence of innovative activities; a cross country and cross-sectors comparative analysis. Research Policy, 30, 1139–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad, A. (2009). The growth of firms: A survey of theories and empirical evidence. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Coad, A., & Hölzl, W. (2010). Firm growth: Empirical analysis, papers on economics and evolution 10-02. Jena: Max Planck Institute of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coad, A., & Rao, R. (2008). Innovation and firm growth in high-tech sectors: A quantile regression approach. Research Policy, 37(4), 633–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad, A., & Rao, R. (2010). Firm growth and R&D expenditure. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 19(2), 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1989). Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D. The Economic Journal, 99(397), 569–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daunfeldt, S.O., Elert, N., Johansson, D. (2010). The economic contribution of high-growth firms: Do definitions matter?, Ratio Working Papers 151, The Ratio Institute.

  • Davis, S. J., Haltiwanger, J., & Schuh, S. (1996). Job creation and destruction. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F. (1997). Measuring growth: Methodological considerations and empirical results. In R. Donckels & A. Miettinen (Eds.), Entrepreneurship and SME Research: On its way to the next millennium (pp. 190–216). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F., Davidsson, P., & Gartner, W. B. (2003). Arriving at the high-growth firm. Journal of Business Venturing, 18, 189–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutschmann, A. (1991). America’s fastest risers. Fortune, October, 46–68.

  • European Commission. (2010). European innovation scoreboard 2009. Luxemburg: SEC.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2011). Policies in support of high-growth innovative SMEs. Bonn: An INNO-Grips Policy Brief by empirica Communication and Technology Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabrizio, K. R. (2009). Absorptive capacity and the search for innovation. Research Policy, 38(2), 255–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkenhall, B., Junkka, F. (2009): High-growth firms in Sweden 19972007. Working paper 2009–04, The Swedish Agency for growth policy analysis.

  • Fritsch, M., & Mueller, P. (2008). The effect of new business formation on regional development over time: the case of Germany. Small Business Economics, 30(1), 15–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, M., & Weyh, A. (2006). How large are the direct employment effects of new businesses? An empirical investigation for West Germany. Small Business Economics, 27, 245–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garnsey, E., Stam, E., & Heffernan, P. (2006). New firm growth: Exploring processes and paths. Industry and Innovation, 13(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les Inegalités Economiques. Applications: Aux Inégalités des Richesses, a la Concentration des Entreprises, Aux Populations des Villes, Aux Statistiques des Familles, etc., d’une Loi Nouvelle: La Loi de l’Effect Proportionnel. Paris: Sirey.

  • Griffith, R., Redding, S., & Van Reenen, J. (2003). R&D and absorptive capacity: Theory and empirical evidence. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(1), 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffith, R., Redding, S., & van Reenen, J. (2004). Map** the two faces of R&D: productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86, 883–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, P. E., & Oulton, N. (1996). Growth and size of firms. The Economic Journal, 106, 1242–1252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Johansson, D. (2010). Gazelles as job creators—A survey and interpretation of the evidence. Small Business Economics, 35, 227–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hölzl, W. (2009). Is the R&D behaviour of fast-growing SMEs different? Evidence from CIS III data for 16 countries. Small Business Economics, 33, 59–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull, L., & Arnold, R. (2008). New Zealand firm growth as change in turnover. Wellington, NZ: Ministry of Economic Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lokshin, B., Belderbos, R., & Carree, M. (2008). The productivity effects of internal and external R&D: Evidence from a dynamic panel data model. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 70(3), 399–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-García, P., & Puente, S. (2012). What makes a high-growth firm? A dynamic probit analysis using Spanish firm-level data. Small Business Economics, 39(4), 1029–1041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2008). Measuring entrepreneurship: A digest of indicators. OECD-Eurostat entrepreneurship indicators program.

  • Parker, S. C., Storey, D. J., & van Witteloostuijn, A. (2010). What happens to gazelles? The importance of dynamic management strategy. Small Business Economics, 35, 203–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schreyer, P. (2000). High-growth Firms and Employment, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2000/3, Paris.

  • Segarra, A., & Teruel, M. (2011). Productivity and R&D sources: Evidence for Catalan firms. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 20(8), 727–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., Whittington, G. (1968). Growth, profitability and valuation. Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge, Occasional Paper, No 7. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Smallbone, D., Leigh, R., & North, D. (1995). The characteristics and strategies of high growth SMEs. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour and Research, 1(3), 44–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stam, E., & Wennberg, K. (2009). The roles of R & D in new firm growth. Small Business Economics, 33, 77–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. (1994). Understanding the small business sector. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, J. (1997). Gibrat’s legacy. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 40–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teruel, M. (2010). Gibrat’s law and the learning process. Small Business Economics, 34(4), 355–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (1992). Firm size, firm growth, and the persistence of chance: Testing Gibrat’s Law with establishment data for Lower Saxony, 1978–1989. Small Business Economics, 4, 125–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are very much indebted to participants at the Workshop on Firm Growth and Innovation (Tarragona 28th–29th June 2012), Encuentro de Economía Aplicada (Huelva, 2011) and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and in particular to Alex Coad, David Audretsch and Marco Vivarelli. This paper is part of the research done with the financial support of the Ministry of Innovation and Science (project ECO2009-08735) and the Consolidated Group of Research 2009-SGR-907. We are grateful to Verònica Gombau for her research support. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Agustí Segarra.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Segarra, A., Teruel, M. High-growth firms and innovation: an empirical analysis for Spanish firms. Small Bus Econ 43, 805–821 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-014-9563-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-014-9563-7

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation