Log in

Honey, I shrunk the kids’ benefits—revisiting intergenerational conflict in OECD countries

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Intergenerational conflict may arise when the interests of different age groups do not align. We examine cross-country data to find evidence for this conflict in OECD countries. We derive our results from a FGLS estimation model, which is complemented by a System-GMM estimation to account for potential endogeneity. The data are from a panel of 22 OECD countries over the time period 1985–2005. We find little support for intergenerational conflict in general; however, those who are close to statutory retirement age dislike public expenditure on families and education because, once they retire, they will have less income compared to their work income. This effect is transitory, however, implying a change in voting behavior during retirement age.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An expanding welfare state does not per se imply intergenerational conflict. No such conflict arises when public spending continues to be proportional to changing cohort sizes.

  2. In the remainder of the paper, we disregard this argument for empirical reasons as in our setting the national political equilibrium cannot be directly inferred from it.

  3. Unfortunately, the Hansen test is not robust to the number of instruments included. As the number of instruments increases, the Hansen test also tends to accept H 0 too often (cf. Roodman 2009). However, currently there is no rule for determining the optimal number of instruments. Roodman (2009) argues that one should reduce the number dramatically to investigate possible distortions. In the present study, there is a natural upper bound based on the number of countries in the sample. Roodman proposed two possibilities for decreasing the instrument count. The first is to use only some lags as instruments. Hence, we used only lags one and two because the correlation should decrease with the time lag. The second alternative is to ‘collapse’ the instrument matrix. This option creates only one instrument for each not strictly exogenous variable and lag distance. Otherwise, the instrument matrix contains instruments for each variable, lag distance, and time period.

  4. Hence, strictly speaking, the variable is not ‘(log) family benefits per child’ but ‘(log) family benefits per 1,000 children’.

  5. These countries are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom, and the United States.

  6. These countries are Belgium (1995), Luxembourg (1995, 2005), and the United States (1995). We omit these three countries in the subsequent analysis.

  7. Note that we do not have the problem of perfect multicollinearity here because we omit the youngest age group. Furthermore, the two variables Child and SUB524 are not defined with the same denominator. Thus, our control variables do not control for the entire age structure.

  8. The Federalism Index is not available for Turkey. EHII data are missing for Switzerland, the year 2005 for all countries and for Belgium (2000), Luxembourg (2000), and Portugal (1995, 2000). Decommodification cannot be analyzed for Greece, Luxembourg, Portugal, Spain, or Turkey because of missing observations.

  9. We use V70up here to allow for a better comparison with the remaining regressions in Table 3. However, we also tested for the effect of the group of all retirees (i.e., V65up) and found analogous insignificant coefficients, with the exception of family benefits as a percentage of GDP, where the coefficient of V65up is weakly significant and negative (this is due to the inclusion of those aged 65–69, who strongly oppose family benefits, as shown below).

  10. The negative (but insignificant) coefficient in the ‘per child’ specifications (regressions (4)–(6)) may be interpreted as a reflection of Becker’s (1960) quantity-quality tradeoff with respect to children. Under the ceteris paribus condition, the same share of GDP is assumed to be allocated to family benefits, i.e., total spending is said to remain unchanged while the population share of children is rising. Hence, more children have to be accommodated by the same amount of resources, implying that spending per child must fall.

  11. This is in contrast to Brunner and Balsdon (2004) and Cattaneo and Wolter (2009), who argue that retirees’ remaining life expectancy is probably too short to selfishly support investments that increase the pie. However, these studies are not directly comparable to our approach as they use survey data at a sub-national level in single countries (the United States, Switzerland). Our findings are thus closer to Lindert (1996) and Busemeyer (2007).

  12. GDP per capita might be viewed as a truly endogenous variable. Taking account of this in our System-GMM estimation does not change our results, however, so we remain with our initial estimation model. The results of this exercise are available from the authors upon request.

  13. The F-statistic for each regression is reported to test for the overall significance of the variables. However, the Hansen test is not the χ 2 test statistic but the p-value of the corresponding test. The reason for this change in notation is that a large p-value, i.e., a value close to one, indicates a misspecification of the test. This is because the Hansen test is not robust to the inclusion of too many instruments (Roodman 2009). We can also infer directly from the p-value that the test is never significant at conventional levels. Thus, we can accept the null hypothesis of exogeneity of the instruments.

  14. Note, however, that we do not obtain this result for the ‘per child’ specification (not shown here).

  15. The per child and per school-ager one-way fixed effects regressions, which are not shown here, reveal that the effect of the V6569 age group is more dominant on educational expenditure than on family benefits. However, the results are not so different that our previous conclusions change.

  16. Lott and Kenny (1999), for the United States, and Aidt and Dallal (2008), for Western Europe, show substantial increases of the social spending share in GDP as a consequence of women’s suffrage.

  17. The precise drop in consumption around the time of retirement is estimated to be substantial. Mariger (1987) estimates a reduction of 43 % and Bernheim et al. (2001) of 10–20 % for the United States. Banks et al. (1998) finds a 35 % decline for the United Kingdom.

  18. Our argument should not be misunderstood as a case for welfare state expansion due to presumed old-age poverty. Retirees’ wealth may be sufficiently high to guarantee a decent living; nevertheless, any drop in replacement income may be viewed as an unpleasant reduction in the standard of living. This appears to be especially true when children have not yet ‘flown the nest’.

  19. To provide a first impression of what we might expect, we included Polity IV’s (Marshall and Jaggers 2008) democracy variable into our empirical model. Obviously, our country sample does not show a lot of variation in this variable, so it does not come as a surprise that the results of this exercise are not significantly different from our benchmark estimations. However, at least education expenditure per GDP seems to be significantly negatively affected by the democracy variable in some specifications, indicating that intergenerational conflict only arises when the elderly have the opportunity to out-vote the young. All results are available from the authors upon request.

References

  • Adserà, A., & Boix, C. (2002). Trade, democracy, and the size of the public sector: the political underpinnings of openness. International Organization, 56, 229–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Dallal, B. (2008). Female voting power: the contribution of women’s suffrage to the growth of social spending in Western Europe (1869–1969). Public Choice, 134, 391–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • American Association of Retired People (AARP) (2002). The grandparent study 2002 report. http://assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/general/gp_2002.pdf.

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K., Engler, S., Potolidis, P., Gerber, M., & Leimgruber, P. (2010). Comparative political data set 1960–2008. Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.

  • Baltagi, B. H. (2005). Econometric analysis of panel data (3rd ed.). Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J., Blundell, R., & Tanner, S. (1998). Is there a retirement savings puzzle? The American Economic Review, 88, 769–788.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. In G. S. Becker (Ed.), Demographic and economic change in developed countries (pp. 225–256). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., Skinner, J., & Weinberg, S. (2001). What accounts for the variation in retirement wealth among U.S. households? The American Economic Review, 91, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, B. (2008). Financial transfers from living parents to adult children. Who is helped and why? American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67, 2007–2239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braude, J. (2001). Generational conflict? Some cross-country evidence (Discussion Paper Series No. 2001.06). Bank of Israel.

  • Brunner, E., & Balsdon, E. (2004). Intergenerational conflict and the political economy of school spending. Journal of Urban Economics, 56, 369–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, E. K. (1975). Why the social insurance budget is too large in a democracy. Economic Inquiry, 13, 373–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burgoon, B. (2006). On welfare and terror: social welfare policies and political-economic roots of terrorism. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 176–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busemeyer, M. R. (2007). Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies, 1980–2001. Journal of European Public Policy, 14, 582–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castles, F. G. (1994). On religion and public policy: does catholicism make a difference? European Journal of Political Research, 25, 19–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cattaneo, M. A., & Wolter, S. C. (2009). Are the elderly a threat to educational expenditures? European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 225–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coile, C., & Gruber, J. (2007). Future social security entitlements and the retirement decision. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89, 234–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., Batinti, A., Bose, F., Kim, Y., & Pietrantonio, R. (2013, forthcoming). Public choice and the modern welfare state. In W. F. Shughart, L. Razzolini, & M. Reksulak (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (2nd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

  • Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1996). A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Economic Review, 10, 565–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Es**-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Es**-Andersen, G., & Sarasa, S. (2002). The generational conflict reconsidered. Journal of European Social Policy, 12, 5–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fanti, L., & Gori, L. (2009). Population and neoclassical economic growth: a new child policy perspective. Economics Letters, 104, 27–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fanti, L., & Gori, L. (2011). Child policy ineffectiveness in an overlap** generations small open economy with human capital accumulation and public education. Economic Modelling, 28, 404–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R., & Rogerson, R. (2001). The determinants of public education expenditures: longer-run evidence from the states. Journal of Education Finance, 27, 567–584.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (1997). Why the United States led in education: lessons from secondary school expansion, 1910 to 1940 (NBER Working Paper No. 6144). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Gradstein, M., & Kaganovich, M. (2004). Aging population and education finance. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2469–2485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D. S. (1984). Consumption during retirement: the missing link in the life cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics, 66, 1–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50, 1029–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, A. R., Evans, W. N., & Schwab, R. M. (2001). Education spending in an aging America. Journal of Public Economics, 81, 449–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2009). Penn world table version 6.3. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania.

  • Holy See (2008). Catholics—percentage of the population. The Holy See, Congregation for the Clergy. http://www.clerus.org/clerus/dati/2008-12/05-6/proportioncathos08.htm.

  • Kelley, D. G. (2013). The political economy of unfunded public pension liabilities. Public Choice. doi:10.1007/s11127-012-0049-3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krieger, T., & Traub, S. (2011). Wie hat sich die intragenerationale Umverteilung in der staatlichen Säule des Rentensystems verändert? Ein internationaler Vergleich auf Basis von LIS-Daten. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 231, 266–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ladd, H. F., & Murray, S. E. (2001). Intergenerational conflict reconsidered: county demographic structure and the demand for public education. Economics of Education Review, 20, 343–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liebman, J. B., Luttmer, E. F. P., & Seif, D. G. (2009). Labor supply responses to marginal social security benefits: evidence from discontinuities. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 1119–1284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindert, P. H. (1994). The rise of social spending, 1880–1930. Explorations in Economic History, 31, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert, P. H. (1996). What limits social spending? Explorations in Economic History, 33, 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Logan, J. R., & Spitze, G. D. (1995). Self-interest and altruism in intergenerational relations. Demography, 32, 353–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., & Kenny, L. W. (1999). Did women’s suffrage change the size and scope of government? Journal of Political Economy, 107, 1163–1198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariger, R. (1987). A life-cycle consumption model with liquidity constraints: theory and empirical results. Econometrica, 55, 533–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2008). Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2008. Center for Systemic Peace and George Mason University.

  • Montén, A., & Thum, M. (2010). Ageing municipalities, gerontocracy and fiscal competition. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 235–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C. B., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Internationally common features of public old-age pensions, and their implications for models of the public sector. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 4(1).

  • OECD (2011). Ageing and employment policies—statistics on average effective age of retirement. Paris.

  • Pampel, F. C., & Williamson, J. B. (1985). Age structure, politics, and cross-national patterns of public pension expenditures. American Sociological Review, 50, 782–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1997). Demographic structure and the political economy of public education. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 16, 48–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106, 997–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samanni, M., Teorell, J., Kumlin, S., & Rothstein, B. (2010). The QoG social policy dataset, version 22 Feb 10. http://www.qog.pol.gu.se.

  • Scruggs, L. (2006). Welfare entitlements data set: a comparative institutional analysis of eighteen welfare states, version 1.2. University of Connecticut. http://sp.uconn.edu/~scruggs/wp.htm.

  • Scruggs, L., & Allan, J. (2006). Welfare-state decommodification in 18 OECD countries: a replication and revision. Journal of European Social Policy, 16, 55–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelton, C. A. (2008). The aging population and the size of the welfare state: is there a puzzle? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 647–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjoblom, K. (1985). Voting for social security. Public Choice, 45, 225–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, S. (1994). How women legislate. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (2009). World population prospects: the 2008 revision population database. United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. http://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp2008/index.htm.

  • UTIP (2008). Estimated household income inequality data set. University of Texas Inequality Project. http://utip.gov.utexas.edu/data.html.

  • World Bank (2010). World development indicators. Washington: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are indebted to two anonymous reviewers and the editor, William F. Shughart II, for their excellent comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tim Krieger.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Krieger, T., Ruhose, J. Honey, I shrunk the kids’ benefits—revisiting intergenerational conflict in OECD countries. Public Choice 157, 115–143 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0064-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0064-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation