Log in

Inclusive and Exclusive Social Preferences: A Deweyan Framework to Explain Governance Heterogeneity

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper wishes to problematize the foundations of production governance and offer an analytical perspective on the interrelation between agents’ preferences, strategic choice, and the public sphere (defined by impacts of choices on ‘publics’ who do not have an input in strategic choice, and by contextual conditions). The value is in the idea of preferences being social in nature and in the application both to the internal stakeholders of the organisation and its impacts on people outside. Using the concept of ‘strategic failure’ we suggest that social preferences reflected in deliberative social praxis can reduce false beliefs and increase individual wellbeing. From this approach, the paper offers a taxonomy of production organisations, based on social preferences about two variables: (i) the governance form (i.e. ownership and control rights) (ii) other strategic decisions that characterize the management of a company at a more operational level, once its fundamental legal form has been chosen. Each dimension (governance and strategic decisions processes) is then categorised alongside two basic preferences: towards inclusion or exclusion of ‘publics’ that have no substantial access to decision power about these variables. Our framework explains governance heterogeneity by contrasting exclusive and inclusive social preferences in cooperatives, social enterprises, as well as traditional corporations. A discussion of the evolution of social preferences and organizational forms is addressed through examples and regional experiences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (United Kingdom)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The idea of externalities has been widely acknowledge in economics. As we explain later in the paper, however, our approach differ from market failure, supporting the necessity of develo** complex coordination mechanisms aimed at discovering complex connections through enquiry and deliberation, beyond the price mechanism. This can be justified because external effects may need to be discovered but also, and more crucially, because it is from the choice of processes and praxis that wider social consequences derive. Moreover, deliberative processes originate social outcomes that are at least partially intended and governed, whilst the price mechanism generates externalities, which are not part of the objective function of the decision-maker (at last formally).

  2. According to standard views in economics, the State is viewed as acting for the public interests against market failures or, as the Chicago school suggests, as the maker of regulatory policies which are nonetheless captured by specific industries for their own private interest. These perspectives and debate are reviewed by Chang (1997).

  3. In Sandel’s view, the temptation to decontextualize choice from its context has seduced Rawls (1971) who, whilst seeking a construct for achieving just choices, had to cut bridges with individual identity and experience (Sandel 1982; Quinn et al. 1997). This is however a problematic argument that would deserve a wider debate. In Rawl’s defence, the pre-commitment to the creation of an unbiased normative framework can be considered as a necessary condition for the development of the type of democratic interaction envisaged for example in the pragmatist approach.

  4. Market failure theory has emphasised that in most circumstances individual preferences have external (positive or negative) implications, although these are considered mainly as indirect effects of private action, which can be explained by the perfectibility of market institutions, as for externalities and market power (see also footnote 1).

  5. Building on the limitations of inductive reasoning, Taleb (2007) has recently attributed to rare improbable events, which are not knowledgeable through empiricism, the main reason of contextual uncertainty.

  6. Typically marking internal practices about decisions on incentives, investments, inter-firm coordination, industrial relations, community involvement, environmental and consumer policy.

  7. Autonomous motivation that stems from extrinsic but internalised values and rules, in this sense, is similar to the autonomy of intrinsic motivation, which is typically defined in terms of the person being interested in the activity for its own sake (Gagné and Deci 2005; Deci and Ryan 1990).

  8. Academia has also been argued to have a specific policy role in selecting and weighting beliefs. Within economics and business, in particular, the discipline has historically exerted strong influence on economic policies as well as in sha** the nature of businesses and their strategies (Currie et al. 2010; Fleckenstein 1997).

  9. The perspective is different from stakeholder theory, where the inclusion of stakeholder interests is typically presented in the context of win–win situations that emerge spontaneously and despite a conventional governance structure.

  10. In Italy, after 1924, during fascism, and until the end of the war, all civic and economic associations had been forbidden by law, thus putting a halt to the diffusion of cooperatives.

  11. Over the last 30 years, in Italy cooperation entered a clear growing pattern. In 2001 cooperative firms represented 1.2 % of firms counting for about 6 % of the total employment (ISTAT 2008). Using national census data Zamagni (2006) observes that during 1990–2000 the overall occupation grew by 60.1 % within cooperatives, contributing to one-fourth of the overall occupational growth for the decade.

  12. Article 45 states: “The Republic recognises the social function of co-operation of a mutualistic, non-speculative nature. The law promotes and encourages co-operation through appropriate means and ensures its character and purposes through adequate controls…”.

  13. In the Trentino region, where cooperation has a long-standing tradition, national legislation was anticipated by a regional law in 1989.

  14. In 1994, Issan, an international research and policy network on cooperative and social enterprises later named Euricse, was created in collaboration with the cooperatives federation, the representative association for commerce and tourism and the Faculty of Economics at the University of Trento, in the Trentino Region. Membership was later extended to ensure the development of the initiative and gain international visibility. The institutional recognition of cooperative models was strengthened further in 1997 when the Third Sector National Forum was officially instituted at the national level and recognised by the government as representative of the sector’s interests, and in 1999 when sectorial data started to be collected in periodic census by the national statistical institute, ISTAT.

  15. Differently from the UK, in some countries demutualisation is not an option. If it were, as the UK case shows, opportunistic behaviours of members or managers would be incentivised. In fact, because cooperatives accumulate indivisible reserves over time, selling an established cooperative permits members to appropriate all the value accumulated by previous members, placing the continuity of cooperative firms in jeopardy (Tortia 2007).

References

  • Amable, B. (2000). Institutional complementarity and diversity of social systems of innovation and production. Review of International Political Economy, 7(4), 645–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, B. (1994). Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Avio, K. L. (2002). Three problems of social organization: institutional law and economics meets Habermasian law and democracy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26, 501–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A., & Ellman, M. (2012). The effects of organization design on employee preferences. In J. E. R. Costa & J. M. R. Marti (Eds.), Towards a new theory of the firm: Humanizing the firm and the management profession. Fundacion BBVA: Bilbao.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A., & Ellman, M. (2013). The contributions of behavioural economics to understanding and advancing the sustainability of worker cooperatives. Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organisational Diversity, 2(1), 75–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A., & Putterman, L. G. (1998). Economics, values, and organization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Berlin, I. (1958/1969). Two concepts of liberty. In I. Berlin (Ed.), Four essays on liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birchall, J. (2001). The new mutualism in public policy. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borzaga, C. (2004). The third sector in Italy. In A. Evers & J.-L. Laville (Eds.), The third sector in Europe (pp. 45–62). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borzaga, C., Depedri, S., & Tortia, E. (2011). Organisational variety in market economies and the role of co-operative and social enterprises: A plea for economic pluralism. Journal of Co-operative Studies, 44(1), 19–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 75–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Polanía Reyes, S. (2009). Economic incentives and social preferences: A preference-based Lucas critique of public policy, CESifo Working Paper, No. 2734.

  • Boyer, R. (2005). Coherence. Diversity, and the evolution of capitalisms—the institutional complementarity hypothesis, evolutionary and institutional economics review, 2(1), 43–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branston, J. R., Cowling, K., & Sugden, R. (2006). Corporate governance and the public interest. International Review of Applied Economics, 20(2), 189–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Vanberg, V. J. (1991). The market as a creative process. Economics and Philosophy, 7, 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (1997). The economics and politics of regulation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21(6), 703–728.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J. (1989). The economic basis of deliberative democracy. Social Philosophy and Policy, 6(2), 25–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowling, K., & Sugden, R. (1998a). Strategic trade policy reconsidered: National rivalry vs free trade vs international cooperation. Kyklos, 51(3), 339–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowling, K., & Sugden, R. (1998b). The essence of the modern corporation: markets, strategic decision-making and the theory of the firm. The Manchester School, 66(1), 59–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowling, K., & Tomlinson, P. (2011). Post the ‘Washington Consensus’: Economic governance and industrial strategies for the twenty-first century. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35, 831–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currie, G., Knights, D., & Starkey, K. (2010). Introduction: A post-crisis critical reflection on business schools. British Journal of Management, 21, 1–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. (1985). Clio and the economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1990). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. New York, NY: Plenum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Defourny, J., & Nyssen, M. (2010). Conceptions of social enterprise and social entrepreneurship in Europe and the United States: Convergences and divergences. Journal of Social Entrepreneurship, 1(1), 32–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewey J. (1917). The need for a recovery of philosophy. [Reproduced in Hickman, L. A. & Alexander, T. M. (1998). The Essential Dewey (Vol. 1, pp. 46–70). Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press].

  • Dewey, J. (1922). Human nature and conduct. [Reproduced in Hickman, L. A. & Alexander, T. M. (1998). The Essential Dewey (Vol. 2, pp. 24–49). Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press].

  • Dewey, J. (1927). The public and its problems. [Reproduced In Hickman, L. A. & Alexander, T. M. (1998). The Essential Dewey (Vol. 1, pp. 293–307). Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press].

  • Dixit, A. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review, 99, 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erdal, D. (2011). Beyond the corporation. Humanity working. London: The Bodley Head.

    Google Scholar 

  • Everett, M. J., & Minkler, A. P. (1993). Evolution and organisational choice in nineteenth-century Britain. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 17(1), 51–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E & Schmidt, K (2001). Theories of fairness and reciprocity: Evidence and economic applications. Working Paper No. 75. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Zurich.

  • Fleckenstein, M. P. (1997). Service learning in business ethics. Journal of Business Ethics, 16, 1347–1351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1997). A constitution for knaves crowds out civic virtues. Economic Journal, 107(443), 1043–1053.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gagné, M., & Deci, E. L. (2005). Self-determination theory and work motivation. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 26, 331–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1992). Economic institutions as social constructions: A framework for analysis. Acta Sociologica, 35(1), 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimalda, G., & Sacconi, L. (2005). The constitution of the not-for-profit organisation: reciprocal conformity to morality. Constitutional Political Economy, 16(3), 249–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guthrie, J. P. (2001). High involvement work practices, turnover and productivity: Evidence from New Zealand. Academy of Management Journal, 44, 180–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habermas, J. (1984). The theory of communicative action (Vol. 1). Boston: Beacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hancher, L., & Moran, M. (1989). Organizing regulatory space. In L. Hancher & M. Moran (Eds.), Capitalism, culture and economic regulation (pp. 271–299). Oxford: Clarendon Press of Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H. (2000). The ownership of enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1944). The road to serfdom. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1982). Shifting involvements. Private interest and public action. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • ISTAT (2008). Le cooperative sociali in Italia, ISTAT, Rome (IT).

  • Joas, H. (1996). The creativity of action. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakatos, I. (1975). Falsification and the methodology of scientific research programmes. In S. Harding (Ed.), Can theories be refuted? (pp. 205–259). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, N. E. (1990). Conceptual notes on the public interest for public administration and policy analysts. Administration and Society, 22, 170–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29(4), 507–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier, A., & Durrer, K. (1992). Ein kognitiv-evolutionäres Modell des wirtschaftspolitischen Prozesses. In U. Witt (Ed.), Studien zur Evolutorischen Ökonomik II (pp. 229–254). Berlin: Duncker und Humblot.

  • Messersmith, J. K., Lepak, D. P., Patel, P. C., & Gould-Williams, J. S. (2011). Unlocking the black box: Exploring the link between high-performance work systems and performance. Journal of Applied Psychology, 96, 1105–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J. S. (1869/1974). On liberty. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1994). The co-evolution of technology, industrial structure, and supporting institutions. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(1), 47–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • North, D. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Offe, C. (2011). Shared social responsibility: The need for and supply of responsible patterns of social action. In Council of Europe (Eds.), Towards a Europe of shared social responsibilities: Challenges and strategies (pp. 15–33). Trends in Social Cohesion 23. Brussels: Council of Europe Publishing.

  • Ostroff, C. (1992). The relationship between satisfaction, attitudes, and performance: An organizational level analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology, 77, 963–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Popper, K. (1959). The logic of scientific discovery. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, K. J., Reed, D. J., Browne, N. M., & Hiers, W. J. (1997). Honesty, individualism, and pragmatic business ethics: Implications for corporate hierarchy. Journal of Business Ethics, 16, 1419–1430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacchetti, S., & Sugden, R. (2009). The organization of production and its publics: Mental proximity, market and hierarchies. Review of Social Economy, 67(3), 289–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacchetti, S., & Sugden, R. (2011). The public interest in economic development and creativity: a knowledge governance perspective, Chap. 11. In B. Dallago & C. Guglielmetti (Eds.), Local economies and global competitiveness. Palgrave: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacconi, L. (2011). From individual responsibility to shared social responsibilities: concepts for a new paradigm. In Council of Europe (Eds.), Towards a Europe of shared social responsibilities: Challenges and strategies (pp. 35–80). Trends in Social Cohesion 23. Brussels: Council of Europe Publishing.

  • Sacconi, L., & Faillo, M. (2010). Conformity, reciprocity and the sense of justice. How social contract-based preferences and beliefs explain norm compliance: the experimental evidence. Constitutional Political Economy, 21(2), 171–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacconi, L., Faillo, M., & Ottone, S. (2011). Contractarian compliance and the `Sense of Justice’: A behavioral conformity model and its experimental support. Analyse & Kritik, 33, 273–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. K. (1998). Social origins of civil society: Explaining the nonprofit sector cross-nationally. VOLUNTAS: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9(3), 213–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandel, M. (1982). Liberalism and the limits of justice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. Journal of Economic History, 7, 149–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1993). Positional objectivity. Philosophy and Public Affairs. [Reprinted in Sen, A. (2002). Rationality and freedom, (pp. 463–83). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press].

  • Sen, A. (2002). Rationality and freedom. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slembeck, T. (1997). The formation of economic policy: A cognitive-evolutionary approach to policy making. Constitutional Political Economy, 8, 225–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spreitzer, G. M. (1995). Psychological empowerment in the workplace: Dimensions, measurement, and validation. Academy of Management Journal, 38, 1442–1465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (2013). Space in an inferno? The organisation of universities and the role of academics. In R. Sugden, M. Valania, & J. Wilson (Eds.), Cooperation and leadership in academia. Reflecting on the roles and responsibilities of university faculty and management. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N. (2007). The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable. Random House.

  • Tortia, E. C. (2007). Self-financing in labor-managed firms (LMFs): Individual capital accounts and bonds. In S. Novkovic & V. Sena (Eds.), Cooperative firms in global markets (pp. 233–261)., Advances in the economic analysis of participatory and labor-managed firms book series, vol. 10 London: Emerald.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tortia, E. C. (2010). The impact of social enterprises on output, employment, and welfare. In L. Becchetti & C. Borzaga (Eds.), The economics of social responsibility. The world of social enterprises. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valentinov, V. (2008). Toward an incentive alignment theory of nonprofit organization. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 5(1), 189–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, R., & Pickett, K. (2010). The spirit level: Why equality is better for everyone. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (2003). Economic policy making in evolutionary perspective. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13, 77–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, I. M. (2000). Inclusion and democracy. Cambridge, MA: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni, V. (2006). L’impresa cooperativa italiana: dalla marginalità alla fioritura. Paper presented at the XIV International Economic History Congress, Session 72, Helsinki.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am very grateful to the anonymous reviewers of this Journal for their critical analysis and substantive suggestions. During the drafting of this manuscript, I benefited from specific conversations with Ermanno Tortia, Jerry Hallier, Lorenzo Sacconi, Carlo Borzaga, Bruce Cronin, Avner Ben-Ner, Vladislav Valentinov, Rob Branston, David Comerford, David Erdal. My thanks go to the participants in the third ICAPE Conference which was held at the University of Massachusetts Amherst, (Mass.) in November 2011. Ideas in the paper were lately discussed at the first Heterodox Microeconomics Workshop at the University of Greenwich, UK, in June 2013. Special thanks go also to my students in socio-economic development for having stimulated discussion and enquiry on the topic. The responsibility for the contents of the paper remains mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Silvia Sacchetti.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sacchetti, S. Inclusive and Exclusive Social Preferences: A Deweyan Framework to Explain Governance Heterogeneity. J Bus Ethics 126, 473–485 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1971-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1971-0

Keywords

Navigation