A Leader–Follower Game on Congestion Management in Power Systems

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Game Theoretic Analysis of Congestion, Safety and Security

Abstract

Since the beginning of power system restructuring and creation of numerous temporal power markets, transmission congestion has become a serious challenge for independent system operators around the globe. On the other hand, in recent years, emission reduction has become a major concern for the electricity industry. As a widely accepted solution, attention has been drawn to renewable power resources promotion. However, penetration of these resources impacts on transmission congestion. In sum, these challenges reinforce the need for new approaches to facilitate interaction between the operator and energy market players defined as the generators (power generation companies) in order to provide proper operational signals for the operator. The main purpose of this chapter is to provide a combination of a leader–follower game theoretical mechanism and multiattribute decision-making for the operator to choose his best strategy by considering congestion-driven and environmental attributes. First the operator (as the leader) chooses K strategies arbitrarily. Each strategy is constituted by emission penalty factors for each generator, the amount of purchased power from renewable power resources, and a bid cap that provides a maximum bid for the price of electrical power for generators who intend to sell their power in the market. For each of the K strategies, the generators (as the followers) determine their optimum bids for selling power in the market. The interaction between generation companies is modeled as Nash-Supply Function equilibrium (SFE) game. Thereafter, for each of the K strategies, the operator performs congestion management and congestion-driven attributes and emission are obtained. The four different attributes are congestion cost, average locational marginal price (LMP) for different system buses, variance of the LMPs, and the generators’ emission. Finally, the operator’s preferred strategy is selected using the Technique for Order Preference by Similarity to Ideal Solution (TOPSIS). The proposed procedure is applied to the IEEE reliability 24-bus test system and the results are analyzed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    In some references in the energy market literature “independent system operator” is used instead of “operator,” and Generation Company or GenCo has been used instead of “generator.” In order to make the chapter more readable, we use “operator” and “generator” throughout the chapter.

Abbreviations

\(C\left( {P_{it} } \right)\) :

Generator i’s cost function for power production when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(C_{E} \left( {P_{it} } \right)\) :

Generator i’s emission cost function when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(\psi_{it}\) :

Emission penalty factor imposed by the operator on the ith generator, \(i = 1, \ldots ,g\) when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(r\) :

Number of renewable power resources, \(r \ge 0\)

\(P_{{{\text{ren}},jt}}\) :

Operator’s amount of purchased renewable power from the resource located in jth bus in Mega Watt when the operator chooses strategy \(t,P_{{{\text{ren}},jt}} \ge 0\), j = 1 ,…, N, \(t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(P_{{{\text{ren}},t}}\) :

Operator’s amount of purchased renewable power when the operator chooses strategy \(t,P_{{{\text{ren}},t}} \ge 0,\,P_{{{\text{ren}},t}} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^{N} {P_{{{\text{ren}},jt}} } ,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(\beta_{\hbox{max} ,t}\) :

Operator’s market bid cap for limiting electricity price on electrical power when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(a_{i} ,\,b_{i} ,\,c_{i}\) :

Generator i’s cost function coefficients

\(a_{Ei} ,\,b_{Ei} \,,c_{Ei}\) :

Generator i’s emission cost function coefficients

\(P_{it}\) :

Power produced by the ith generator, as determined by the operator to maximize social welfare within constraints when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(P_{i}^{\hbox{max} }\) :

Maximum power produced by the ith generator

\(P_{i}^{\hbox{min} }\) :

Minimum power produced by the ith generator

\(P_{Th,kj}^{\hbox{max} }\) :

Thermal power flow limit of the transmission line between buses k and j, \(k,j = 1, \ldots ,N\)

\(P_{St,kj}^{\hbox{max} }\) :

Stability power flow limit of the transmission line between buses k and j, \(k,j = 1, \ldots ,N\)

\(N\) :

Number of transmission buses

\(P_{line,kjt}\) :

Power flows across the transmission line between buses \(k\,{\text{and}}\,j,k,j = 1, \ldots ,N\) when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\({\text{LMP}}_{kt}\) :

Locational marginal price of bus \(k,k = 1, \ldots ,N\) when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(CC_{t}\) :

The operator’s decision matrix M’s \(x_{1t}\) element, i.e., congestion cost when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(ave\_{\text{LMP}}_{t}\) :

The operator’s decision matrix M’s \(x_{2t}\) element, i.e., average locational marginal price (LMP) for different system buses when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(var\_{\text{LMP}}_{t}\) :

The operator’s decision matrix M’s \(x_{3t}\) element, i.e., variance of the LMPs when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(emission_{t}\) :

The operator’s decision matrix M’s \(x_{4t}\) element, i.e., the g generators’ emission when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(g_{n}\) :

Number of generators connected to bus n

\(D\) :

Total electricity demand of all consumers

\(d_{n}\) :

Number of electricity demands connected to bus \(n,\sum\nolimits_{k = 1}^{N} {d_{n} = D}\)

\(P_{{nD_{k} }}\) :

Active power consumption of the kth electricity demand connected to bus n, \(k = 1, \ldots ,d_{n} ,n = 1, \ldots ,N\)

\(SW_{t}\) :

Social welfare when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(g\) :

Number of generators

\(\beta_{it}\) :

The ith generator’s market bid for trading his electrical power in the market when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(\kappa_{t}\) :

The distance of the strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\) from the negative ideal strategy over the sum of distances of this strategy from positive and negative ideal strategy

\(\lambda_{t}\) :

The estimated market clearing price for electrical power when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

\(Y_{i}\) :

The operator strategies’ ith attribute, \(i = 1, \ldots ,4\), i.e., the ith column of the operator’s \(K \times 4\) decision matrix M

\(A\) :

Operator’s \(4 \times 4\) comparison matrix of attributes

\(M\) :

Operator’s \(K \times 4\) decision matrix

\(S_{t}^{*} = \left[ {\psi_{1t}^{*} , \ldots ,\psi_{32t}^{*} ,P_{{{\text{ren}},t}}^{*} ,\beta_{{{ \hbox{max} },t}}^{*} } \right]\) :

The operator’s preferred strategy

\(S = \left\{ {S_{t} = [\psi_{1t} , \ldots ,\psi_{3,t} ,P_{{{\text{ren}},t}} ,\beta_{\hbox{max} ,t} ]\quad\forall t = 1, \ldots ,K} \right\}\) :

The operator’s set of K strategies

\(PI_{t}\) :

Performance index of the power system when the operator chooses strategy \(t,t = 1, \ldots ,K\)

SFE:

Supply function equilibrium

TCM:

Transmission congestion management

TOPSIS:

Technique for order preference by similarity to ideal solution

LMP:

Locational marginal price

PIS:

Positive ideal strategy

NIS:

Negative ideal strategy

References

  1. Abido MA (2003) A niched Pareto genetic algorithm for multiobjective environmental/economic dispatch. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 25(2):97–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Ahmadi H, Lesani H (2014) Transmission congestion management through LMP difference minimization: a renewable energy placement case study. Arab J Sci Eng 39(3):1963–1969

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Bier VM, Hausken K (2013) Defending and attacking a network of two arcs subject to traffic congestion. Reliab Eng Syst Saf 112:214–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bompard E, Correia P, Gross G, Amelin M (2003) Congestion-management schemes: a comparative analysis under a unified framework. IEEE Trans Power Syst 18(1):346–352

    Google Scholar 

  5. Borenstein S, Bushnell J (2000) Electricity restructuring: deregulation or reregulation. Regulation 23:46–52

    Google Scholar 

  6. Chaturvedi KT, Pandit M, Srivastava L (2008) Hybrid neuro-fuzzy system for power generation control with environmental constraints. Energy Convers Manage 49(11):2997–3005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Chen CT (2000) Extensions of the TOPSIS for group decision-making under fuzzy environment. Fuzzy Sets Syst 114(1):1–9

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Conejo AJ, Castillo E, Mínguez R, Milano F (2005) Locational marginal price sensitivities. IEEE Trans Power Syst 20(4):2026–2033

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Conejo AJ, Milano F, García-Bertrand R (2008) Congestion management ensuring voltage stability. In: Proceedings of IEEE power and energy society general meeting-conversion and delivery of electrical energy in the 21st century, 2008 IEEE

    Google Scholar 

  10. de la Torre S, Contreras J, Conejo AJ (2004) Finding multiperiod Nash equilibria in pool-based electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 19(1):643–651

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Dong S, Yang Q, Fu F, Kwak KS (2013) Distributed link scheduling for congestion control in multihop wireless network. In: Proceedings of international conference on IEEE wireless communications and signal processing (WCSP), pp 1–5

    Google Scholar 

  12. Grigg C, Wong P, Albrecht P, Allan R, Bhavaraju M, Billinton R, Singh C (1999) The IEEE reliability test system-1996. A report prepared by the reliability test system task force of the application of probability methods subcommittee. IEEE Trans Power Syst 14(3):1010–1020

    Google Scholar 

  13. Hobbs BF (2001) Linear complementarity models of Nash-Cournot competition in bilateral and POOLCO power markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst on 16(2):194–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Hobbs BF, Helman U, Pang JS (2001) Equilibrium market power modeling for large scale power systems. In: Proceedings of IEEE power engineering society summer meeting, vol 1, pp 558–563

    Google Scholar 

  15. Hobbs BF, Rothkopf MH, O’Neill RP, Hung-po C (ed) (2001) The next generation of electric power unit commitment models, vol 36. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  16. Kaplan SM (2009) Electric power transmission: background and policy issues. US Congressional Research Service, pp 4–5, 14 April 2009

    Google Scholar 

  17. Kirschen D, Strbac G (2004) Fundamentals of power system economics. John Wiley and Sons, New York

    Google Scholar 

  18. Klemperer PD, Meyer MA (1989) Supply function equilibria in oligopoly under uncertainty. Econom J Econom Soci 57(6):1243–1277

    Google Scholar 

  19. Krause T, Andersson G (2006) Evaluating congestion management schemes in liberalized electricity markets using an agent-based simulator. In: Proceedings of IEEE power engineering society general meeting

    Google Scholar 

  20. Kumar A, Sekhar C (2013) Comparison of Sen transformer and UPFC for congestion management in hybrid electricity markets. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 47:295–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Kumar A, Srivastava SC, Singh SN (2005) Congestion management in competitive power market: a bibliographical survey. Electric Power Syst Res 76(1):153–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Kunz F (2013) Improving congestion management: how to facilitate the integration of renewable generation in Germany. Energy J 34(4):55–78

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  23. Lai LL (ed) (2001) Power system restructuring and deregulation: trading, performance and information technology. John Wiley and Sons, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  24. Lee KH (2014) Strategy equilibrium in Stackelberg model with transmission congestion in electricity market. J Electr Eng Technol 9(1):90–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Lee AH, Yang CN, Lin CY (2012) Evaluation of children’s after-school programs in Taiwan: FAHP approach. Asia Pac Educ Rev 13(2):347–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Lin S, Fletcher BA, Luo M, Chinery R, Hwang SA (2011) Health impact in New York city during the northeastern blackout of 2003. Public Health Rep 126(3):384

    Google Scholar 

  27. Liu Y, Wu FF (2007) Impacts of network constraints on electricity market equilibrium. IEEE Trans Power Syst 22(1):126–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Liu Z, Tessema B, Papaefthymiou G, van der Sluis L (2011) Transmission expansion planning for congestion alleviation using constrained locational marginal price

    Google Scholar 

  29. Lise W, Linderhof V, Kuik O, Kemfert C, Östling R, Heinzow T (2006) A game theoretic model of the Nnrthwestern European electricity market—market power and the environment. Energy Policy 34(15):2123–2136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Merriam-Webster dictionary. http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/congestion

  31. Muñoz A, Sánchez-Úbeda EF, Cruz A, Marín J (2010) Short-term forecasting in power systems: a guided tour. In: Proceedings of handbook of power systems II. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 129–160

    Google Scholar 

  32. Orfanos GA, Georgilakis P, Hatziargyriou ND (2013) Transmission expansion planning of systems with increasing wind power integration. IEEE Trans Power Syst 28(2):1355–1362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Porter K (2002) The implications of regional transmission organization design for renewable energy technologies. National Renewable Energy Laboratory, USA

    Google Scholar 

  34. Saaty TL, Vargas LG (2001) Models, methods, concepts and applications of the analytic hierarchy process, vol 1. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  35. Saber AY, Venayagamoorthy GK (2010) Intelligent unit commitment with vehicle-to-grid—a cost-emission optimization. J Power Sources 195(3):898–911

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Saguan M, Keseric N, Dessante P, Glachant JM (2006) Market power in power markets: game theory vs. agent-based approach. In: Proceedings of IEEE/PES transmission and distribution conference and exposition, Latin America, 2006, TDC’06, pp 1–6

    Google Scholar 

  37. Sahraei-Ardakani M, Rahimi-Kian A (2009) A dynamic replicator model of the players’ bids in an oligopolistic electricity market. Electr Power Syst Res 79(5):781–788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Salehizadeh MR, Rahimi‐Kian A, Oloomi‐Buygi M (2014) A multi‐attribute congestion‐driven approach for evaluation of power generation plans. Int Trans Electr Energy Syst. doi:10.1002/etep.1861

  39. Shih HS, Shyur HJ, Lee ES (2007) An extension of TOPSIS for group decision making. Math Comput Model 45(7):801–813

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  40. Son YS, Baldick R (2004) Hybrid coevolutionary programming for Nash equilibrium search in games with local optima. IEEE Trans Evol Comput 8(4):305–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Sun H, Wu J, Ma D, Long J (2014) Spatial distribution complexities of traffic congestion and bottlenecks in different network topologies. Appl Math Model 38(2):496–505

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  42. Telang NG, Jordan KE, Supekar NS (2013) US Patent No. 8,516,121. US Patent and Trademark Office, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  43. Veit DJ, Weidlich A, Krafft JA (2009) An agent-based analysis of the German electricity market with transmission capacity constraints. Energy Policy 37(10):4132–4144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Ventosa M, Baıllo A, Ramos A, Rivier M (2005) Electricity market modeling trends. Energy Policy 33(7):897–913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Visalakshi S, Baskar S (2011) Multiobjective decentralized congestion management using modified NSGA-II. Arab J Sci Eng 36(5):827–840

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Salehizadeh MR, Rahimi-Kian A, Oloomi-Buygi M (2015) Security-based multi-objective congestion management for emission reduction in power system. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst  65:124–135

    Google Scholar 

  47. Wang X, Zhuang J (2011) Balancing congestion and security in the presence of strategic applicants with private information. Eur J Oper Res 212(1):100–111

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  48. Yoon KP, Hwang CL (eds) (1995) Multiple attribute decision making: an introduction. Sage 102–104

    Google Scholar 

  49. Zhang YP, Jiao LW, Chen SS, Yan Z, Wen FS, Ni YX, Wu F (2003) A survey of transmission congestion management in electricity markets. Power Syst Technol 8:1–9

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  50. Zhang Y, Gong DW, Ding Z (2012) A bare-bones multi-objective particle swarm optimization algorithm for environmental/economic dispatch. Inf Sci 192:213–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Zeng M, Luan F, Zhang J, Liu B, Zhang Z (2006) Improved ant colony algorithm (ACA) and game theory for economic efficiency evaluation of electrical power market. In: Proceedings of international conference on IEEE computational intelligence and security, 2006, vol 1, pp 849–854

    Google Scholar 

  52. Zimmerman RD, Murillo-Sánchez CE, Gan D (1997) A MATLAB power system simulation package. http://www.pserc.conrnell.edu/matpower. Accessed 8 Jan 2006

  53. Zou X, Luo X, Peng Z (2008) Congestion management ensuring voltage stability under multicontingency with preventive and corrective controls. In: Proceedings of IEEE power and energy society general meeting-conversion and delivery of electrical energy in the 21st century, 2008, pp 1–8

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank anonymous referees for their helpful suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mohammad Reza Salehizadeh .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix When \(a_{i} = 0\) for at Least One Generator

Appendix When \(a_{i} = 0\) for at Least One Generator

Assume that \(a_{i} = 0\) when \(i = 1, \ldots ,g_{0}\), and \(a_{i} > 0\) when \(i = g_{0} + 1, \ldots ,g,\,1 \le g_{0} \le g\). Taking the limit for (9) gives:

$$\lambda_{t} = \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{(a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} ) \to (0, \ldots ,0)}} \frac{{d + \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{g} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} }}{{\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }}$$
(47)

Separating the terms related to the \(g_{0}\) generators with \(a_{i} = 0\), and the \(g - g_{0}\) generators with \(a_{i} > 0\), gives:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda_{t} & = \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{d + \sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} = \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{d + \sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} \\ & \quad + \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} = 0 + \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{{\beta_{it} }}{{a_{i} }}} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} \\ & = \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\frac{{\beta_{1t} }}{{a_{1} }}}}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} + \cdots + \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\frac{{\beta_{{g_{0} t}} }}{{a_{{g_{0} }} }}}}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{1}{{a_{i} }}} }} \\ & = \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\beta_{1t} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{{a_{1} }}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{{a_{1} }}{{a_{i} }}} }} + \cdots + \mathop {\text{Lim}}\limits_{{\left( {a_{1} , \ldots ,a_{{g_{0} }} } \right) \to \left( {0, \ldots ,0} \right)}} \frac{{\beta_{{g_{0} t}} }}{{\sum_{{i = g_{0} + 1}}^{g} {\frac{{a_{{g_{0} }} }}{{a_{i} }}} + \sum_{i = 1}^{{g_{0} }} {\frac{{a_{{g_{0} }} }}{{a_{i} }}} }} \\ & = \frac{{\beta_{1t} }}{{0 + g_{0} }} + \cdots + \frac{{\beta_{{g_{0} t}} }}{{0 + g_{0} }} = \frac{{\beta_{1t} + \cdots + \beta_{{g_{0} t}} }}{{g_{0} }} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(48)

The calculated \(\lambda_{t}\) will be substituted in (10) and the rest of the calculation procedure will be the same as what we developed for the case of \(a_{i} > 0;i = 1, \ldots ,g\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Salehizadeh, M.R., Rahimi-Kian, A., Hausken, K. (2015). A Leader–Follower Game on Congestion Management in Power Systems. In: Hausken, K., Zhuang, J. (eds) Game Theoretic Analysis of Congestion, Safety and Security. Springer Series in Reliability Engineering. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-13009-5_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-13009-5_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-13008-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-13009-5

  • eBook Packages: EngineeringEngineering (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics

Navigation