Part of the book series: Logic, Argumentation & Reasoning ((LARI,volume 31))

Abstract

This text discusses interdisciplinary exchange and the intellectual obstacles to interdisciplinarity that arise from attempts to talk across conflicting and incommensurable paradigms in different disciplines, from the vantage point of economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Laurent (2012, p. 222) proposed a focus on research programmes as “conceptually coherent entities”.

  2. 2.

    Interdisciplinarity is a word with many meanings and can be considered from many perspectives. There are multiple interdisciplinarities. Following Pombo (2004) I use interdisciplinarity as an umbrella term, meaning a continuum of progressive integration of disciplines, going from the less demanding forms of disciplinary exchange (a simple juxtaposition of disciplines, which retain their full autonomy – let us call this pluri or multidisplinarity) to the complete integration of knowledge, with a new set of common-denominator concepts, which transcends the original disciplines (transdisciplinarity).

  3. 3.

    “Horizontal exchanges” are meant here to designate interactions taking place between different social sciences (e.g. economics, sociology, political science and anthropology). “Vertical exchanges” occur when social sciences take inspiration and seek guidance and insight from lower-level physical, cognitive and life sciences.

  4. 4.

    Economists are the least likely of any social scientists to cite journals outside their field.

  5. 5.

    Similar statements may be found in other “heterodox” national and international organizations, for example the Sociedade Brasileira de Economia Política (https://www.sep.org.br/01_sites/01/index.php/instituicao/estatuto), the Association Française d’Économie Politique (https://assoeconomiepolitique.org/presentation-2/), the Association for Social Economics (https://socialeconomics.org/about/) or the International Initiative for Promoting Political Economy (IIPPE) (http://iippe.org/about-iippe/).

  6. 6.

    http://freakonomics.com/

  7. 7.

    “Ontological integrity” is understood here as a fundamental presupposition of a realist understanding of science and expresses the adequacy of our theorizing in relation to the fundamental nature of the phenomena observed (see Oakley, 1999).

  8. 8.

    A paradigm is an intellectual as well as a sociological category. It corresponds to a specific way of thinking and the set of institutional arrangements within which the scientific activity occurs. The paradigm may be defined by the shared beliefs of a given scientific community regarding fundamental aspects of their discipline (subject matter and understanding of the nature of reality, the tools and language considered suitable for building up knowledge about it, and the commonly held values and appraisal criteria for assessing scientific quality). Scientists working within different paradigms “see different things and see them in different relations one to the other” (Bernstein, 1983; Dow, 2002, 2008; Kuhn, 1996, pp. 148–150; Neves, 2016, p. 500).

  9. 9.

    See Köhn (2017).

  10. 10.

    Bibliographical references to the Knight-Keynes concept of uncertainty significantly declined in mainstream economics journals after the 1950s, a decline paralleled by the corresponding move towards the formalization of economics (Hodgson, 2011). In effect, it was difficult to fit the concept of fundamental uncertainty into a formal model. Yet, according to this author, formalization per se was not the only reason for the decline of the Knight-Keynes concept of uncertainty within mainstream economics circles (chaos theory is mathematized and also did not attract the attention of mainstream economists). Data on publications instead suggests that it is the relevance attributed to building models aimed at reaching useful predictable outcomes that helps explain why the concept was abandoned. In Hodgson’s words: “Uncertainty is not only unquantifiable but it restricts precise prediction. It is thus prevented by a double-lock from entry into the mainstream. Mainstream economics would have to abandon both its obsession with formalization and its primary goal of prediction for the door to be opened.” (idem, pp.165-6).

References

  • Bammer, G., & Smithson, M. (2008). In G. Bammer & M. Smithson (Eds.), Uncertainty and risk: Multidisciplinary perspectives. earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1993). Nobel lecture: The economic way of looking at behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 101(3), 385–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, R. (1983). Beyond objectivism and relativism: Science, hermeneutics, and praxis. University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1994). Economics and contiguous disciplines. In R. Coase (Ed.), Essays on economics and economists (pp. 34–46). The University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D. (2005). The making of an economist redux. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 175–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D., Holt, R. P. F., & Rosser, J. B. (2004). The changing face of mainstream economics. Review of Political Economy, 16(4), 485–499. https://doi.org/10.1080/0953825042000256702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dequech, D. (1999). Institutions and economic behaviour under uncertainty. Estudos Económicos, São Paulo, 29(4), 551–573.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2002). Economic methodology: An inquiry. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2007). Variety of methodological approach in economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 21(3), 447–465. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2007.00510.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2008). A future for schools of thought and pluralism in heterodox economics. In J. Harvey & R. Garnett Jr. (Eds.), Future directions for heterodox economics. The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2012). Foundations for new economic thinking: A collection of essays. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, S. (2016). Uncertainty: A diagrammatic treatment. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 10(3), 1–26. https://doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2016-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M., Ollion, E., & Algan, Y. (2015). The superiority of economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 89–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hacking, I. (2006). The emergence of probability: A philosophical study of early ideas about probability, induction and statistical (2nd ed.). Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1985). The expanding domain of economics. The American Economic Review, 75(6), 53–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. (2011). The eclipse of the uncertainty concept in mainstream economics. Journal of Economic Issues, 45(1), 159–176. https://doi.org/10.2753/JEI0021-3624450109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapp, K. W. (1961). Toward a science of man in society: A positive approach to the integration of social knowledge. Martinus Nijhoff.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kapp, K. W. (1985). In J. Ullmann & R. Preiswerk (Eds.), The humanization of the social sciences. University Press of America.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klamer, A. (2007). Speaking of economics: How to get in the conversation. In Speaking of economics. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Köhn, J. (2017). Uncertainty in economics: A new approach. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. (1996). The structure of scientific revolutions. The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laurent, C. (2012). Plurality of science and rational integration of knowledge. In O. Pombo, J. Torres, J. Symons, & S. Rahman (Eds.), Special sciences and the Unity of science (pp. 219–231). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (2003). Reorienting economics. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. (2000). Economic Imperialism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1), 99–146. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355300554683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, F. (2013). Editor’s introduction. In F. Lee (Ed.), Studies in economic reform and social justice: Social costs of markets and economic theory. Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loasby, B. J. (2001). Time, knowledge and evolutionary dynamics: Why connections matter. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(4), 393–412. https://doi.org/10.1007/PL00003867

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loasby, B. J. (2003). Closed models and open systems. Journal of Economic Methodology, 10(3), 285–306. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350178032000110864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod, M. (2018). What makes interdisciplinarity difficult? Some consequences of domain specificity in interdisciplinary practice. Synthese, 195(2), 697–720. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11229-016-1236-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mearman, A., Berger, S., & Guizzo, D. (2019). What is heterodox economics? Conversations with leading economists. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neves, V. (2012). Sciences as open systems - the case of economics. In O. Pombo, J. Torres, J. Symons, & S. Rahman (Eds.), Special sciences and the unity of science. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neves, V. (2016). What happened to Kapp’s theory of social costs? A case of metatheoretical dispute and dissent in economics. Review of Political Economy, 28(4). https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2016.1208896

  • Neves, V. (2017). Economics and interdisciplinarity: An open-systems approach. Revista de Economia Politica, 37(2). https://doi.org/10.1590/0101-31572017v37n02a05

  • Norgaard, R. B. (1994). Development betrayed: The end of progress and a coevolutionary revisioning of the future. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oakley, A. (1999). Situational analysis and agent rationality: Shackle contra Popper. In C. Sardoni & P. Kriesler (Eds.), Keynes, post Keynesianism and political economy: Essays in honour of Geoff Harcourt (Vol. III). Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pombo, O. (2004). Interdisciplinaridade: Ambições e Limites. Relógio d’ Água Editores.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin, J. (2008). Economists and uncertainty. In G. Bammer & M. Smithson (Eds.), Uncertainty and risk: Multidisciplinary perspectives (pp. 195–203). earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (2006). History of economic analysis (Vol. 22). Taylor & Francis e-Library.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Smithson, M. (2008). The many faces and masks of uncertainty. In G. Bammer & M. Smithson (Eds.), Uncertainty and risk: Multidisciplinary perspectives (pp. 13–25). earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stilwell, F. (2013). Interview with Frank Stillwell. World Economics Association Newsletter, 3(1), 9–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strober, M. (2006). Habits of the mind: Challenges for multidisciplinary engagement. Social Epistemology, 20(3–4), 315–331. https://doi.org/10.1080/02691720600847324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strober, M. (2011). Interdisciplinary conversations: Challenging habits of thought. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vítor Neves .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Neves, V. (2023). The Utopia of Interdisciplinarity: A View from Economics. In: Pombo, O., Gärtner, K., Jesuíno, J. (eds) Theory and Practice in the Interdisciplinary Production and Reproduction of Scientific Knowledge. Logic, Argumentation & Reasoning, vol 31. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-20405-0_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics

Navigation