Log in

Is GDP a Relevant Social Welfare Indicator? A Savers—Spenders Theory Approach

  • Article
  • Published:
The Japanese Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The use of GDP as the main index of progress and welfare of a country has been the subject of a long debate among economists. Using and extending the savers-spenders theory, we analyse the theoretical relationship between GDP and the welfare of a society. This analysis is undertaken using several different overlap** generations models which all take into account the great heterogeneity of consumer behaviour observed in the data (different labour supply choices, different degrees of altruism and/or different degrees of impatience to consume). The results indicate that GDP (per capita) is often a relevant index and is always a decent social welfare indicator.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alonso-Carrera, J., J. Caballé and X. Raurich (2005) “Growth, Habit Formation, and Catching-up with the Joneses”, European Economic Review, Vol. 49, pp. 1665–1691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asheim, G. and M. Weitzman (2001) “Does NNP Growth Indicate Welfare Improvement?”, Economics Letters, Vol. 73, pp. 233–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, L. (1999) “Real Wealth - Use of Gross Domestic Product Figures as Economic Indicator May No Longer Be Valid”, E/The Environmental Magazine, May.

  • Barro, R (1974) “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82, pp. 1095–1117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G (1981) A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (1996) Accounting for Tastes, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E. and Z. Rzakhanov (2000) “Fertility, Migration and Altruism”, NBER Working Paper, No. 7545.

  • Borjas, G. J. (1994) “The Economics of Immigration”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 32, pp. 1667–1717.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D., B. K. Rhee and C. Rhee (1999) “Does Cultural Origin Affect Saving Behavior? Evidence from Immigrants”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 48, pp. 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cazzavillan, G. and P. Pintus (2004) “Robustness of Multiple Equilibria in OLG Economies”, Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 7, pp. 456–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick, B. (1978) “The Effect of Americanization on the Earnings of Foreign-born Men”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86, pp. 897–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, S. and T. Mitra (1999) “On the Welfare Significance of National Product for Economic Growth and Sustainable Development”, Japanese Economic Review, Vol. 50, pp. 422–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Nardi, M. (2004) “Wealth Inequality and Intergenerational Links”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 71, pp. 743–768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. (1965) “National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model”, American Economic Review, Vol. 55, pp. 1126–1150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (1978) “Government Debt, Human Capital, and Bequests in a Life Cycle Model”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86, pp. 505–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durkin, J. T. (1998) “Immigration, Assimilation and Growth”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 11, pp. 273–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (1986) “Time Preference and International Labor Migration”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 38, pp. 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaumont, D. and A. Mesnard (2000) “Altruism and International Labour Migration”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 113–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laitner, J. (2001) “Secular Changes in Wealth Inequality and Inheritance”, Economic Journal, Vol. 111, pp. 691–721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambrecht, S., Ph Michel and J. P. Vidal (2005) “Public Pensions and Growth”, European Economic Review, Vol. 49, pp. 1261–1281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R and L. Rap** (1969) “Real Wages, Employment and Inflation”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77, pp. 721–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G. (2000) “The Savers-Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy”, American Economic Review, Vol. 90, pp. 120–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michel, Ph and P. Pestieau (1998) “Fiscal Policy in a Growth Model with Both Altruistic and Non-Altruistic Agents”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 64, pp. 682–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — and — (2005) “Fiscal Policy with Agents Differing in Altruism and Ability”, Economica, Vol. 72, pp. 121–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, — and J. P. Vidal (1998) “Labor Migration and Redistribution with Alternative Assimilation Policies: the Small Economy Case”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 28, pp. 363–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, E. Thibault and J. P. Vidal (2006) “Intergenerational Altruism and Neoclassical Growth Models”, Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, Elsevier-North Holland, Chapter 15 (Vol. 2), pp. 1055–1106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2014) “Is Migration Good for the Economy?”, Migration Policy Debates, No. 2.

  • Pestieau, P. and E. Thibault (2012) “Love thy Children or Money - Reflections on Debt Neutrality and Estate Taxation”, Economic Theory, Vol. 50, pp. 31–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1928) “A Mathematical Theory of Saving”, Economic Journal, Vol. 38, pp. 543–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rangazas, P. (1991) “Human Capital Investment in Wealth-Constrained Families with Two-Sided Altruism”, Economics Letters, Vol. 35, pp. 137–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1958) “An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With and Without the Social Contrivance of Money”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 66, pp. 467–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1979) “The Welfare Basis of Real Income. Comparisons: A Survey”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 17, pp. 1–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smetters, K. (1999) “Ricardian Equivalence: Long-Run Leviathan”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 73, pp. 395–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tcha, M. J. (1995a) “Altruism, Conflict and the Migration Decision”, International Regional Science Review, Vol. 18, pp. 289–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1995b) “Altruism, Household Size and Migration”, Economics Letters, Vol. 49, pp. 441–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1996) “Altruism and Migration: Evidence from Korea and United States”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 44, pp. 859–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thibault, E. (2001) “Labor Immigration and Long-Run Welfare in a Growth Model with Heterogenous Agents and Endogenous Labor Supply”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 14, pp. 391–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2005) “Existence and Specific Characters of Rentiers: A Savers-Spenders Theory Approach”, Economic Theory, Vol. 25, pp. 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil, P. (1987) “Love thy Children. Reflections on the Barro Debt Neutrality Theorem”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 377–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. (1976) “On the Welfare Significance of National Product in a Dynamic Economy”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90, pp. 156–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Thibault, E. Is GDP a Relevant Social Welfare Indicator? A Savers—Spenders Theory Approach. JER 68, 333–351 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1111/jere.12116

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1111/jere.12116

JEL Classification Numbers

Navigation