Log in

Disaggregation for efficiency analysis

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Efficiency analysis is a popular technique used to compare the performances of Decision Making Units (DMUs). Procedures to aggregate DMU-level efficiency and related efficiency concepts to obtain group-specific counterparts have been proposed recently. In this paper, we suggest procedures for the opposite direction: disaggregate DMU-level efficiency and related efficiency concepts into output-specific counterparts. For being largely applicable, based on economic optimization behaviour, easy to use and to interpret, these procedures establish a novel toolkit for efficiency analysis practitioners.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For early works on this approach, refer to Afriat (1972), Hanoch and Rothschild (1972), Diewert and Parkan (1983) and Varian (1984).

  2. See, for example, Färe et al. (1994), Cooper et al. (2004), Coelli et al. (2005), Cooper et al. (2007), Fried et al. (2008), and Cook and Seiford (2009) for reviews on the two approaches.

  3. See Banker and Maindiratta (1988) and Färe and Grosskopf (1995) for the interrelationship between the two. Farrell (1957) relates them by using the concept of allocative efficiency. See Section 3 for more detail.

  4. Their allocation procedure also fits with efficiency analysis models integrating information on the internal production structure. See, for example, Salerian and Chan (2005), Despic et al. (2007), Cherchye et al. (2008), Färe and Grosskopf (2000), Färe et al. (2007), Tone and Tsutsui (2009), Cherchye et al. (2015), Ding et al. (2017), Silva (2018), and Walheer (2018d); and Remark 1 in Section 4.

  5. Note that our modelling is applicable to standard models as well as those assuming a particular internal structure of the production process. See Remark 1 in Section 4 for more detail.

  6. Inspirations could be found in Cherchye et al. (2016) that have defined profit efficiency (and directional distance function) in a similar context. See also Walheer and Zhang (2018) for dynamic profit efficiency settings.

  7. Note that here we adopt a so-called relaxed convexity approach in the sense that we only require the input requirement sets to be convex (see Petersen (1990) and Bogetoft (1996)) and not the production possibility sets, but it is straightforward to adapt the following with the stronger assumption of convex production possibility sets. See, for example, Walheer (2018b).

  8. For formal definitions of Tq and Iq(yq), see Petersen (1990) and Bogetoft (1996), and Cherchye et al. (2013) and Cherchye et al. (2016).

  9. \(\widehat T^q\) is directly related to Tq, since \(\widehat T^q = \{ \lambda ({\mathbf{x}}^q,{\mathbf{y}}^q) \in T^q,\forall \lambda > 0\}\). For formal definitions of \(\widehat T^q\) and \(\widehat I^q({\mathbf{y}}^q)\), see Petersen (1990) and Bogetoft (1996), and Walheer (2018b).

  10. In practice, it is enough to evaluate cost efficiency to non-increasing returns-to-scale and compare this efficiency measurement to CEq(yq, xq, wq). If they are equal, cost scale inefficiency is due to decreasing returns-to-scale. Otherwise, cost scale inefficiency is due to increasing returns-to-scale.

  11. Note that we adopt here a variable-returns-to-scale setting, there are no reasons not to do the same under a constant returns-to-scale assumption (i.e., by adding Axiom 5). Formal definitions of these sets can easily be obtained by modifying the setting considered in Podinovski and Kuosmanen (2011) to our specific setting.

  12. Note that, y, x, and w are not the standard definitions of the outputs, the inputs, and the input prices at the DMU-level but are here matrices. The difference is due to our consideration of an output-specific setting. Nevertheless, it is easy to relate our setting to more standard efficiency analysis models. In fact, these models are a particular case of ours. See Remark 1 in Section 4 for a discussion.

  13. The weights αq(x, w; 1) generalize the weights in the disaggregation procedures of Cherchye et al. (2013), Cherchye et al. (2016), and Walheer (2018b, 2018c); and are consistent with the weights found for aggregate procedures by, for example, Färe and Zelenyuk (2003, 2005, 2007), Färe et al. (2004), Zelenyuk (2006, 2015), Färe and Karagiannis (2017), and Walheer (2018a, 2018e).

  14. Inspirations could be found in Cherchye et al. (2016) and Walheer and Zhang (2018) that have defined directional distance function in a similar context.

  15. The (input-oriented) technical efficiency is also the reciprocal of the (input) distance function introduced by Shephard (1953, 1970):

    \(\frac{1}{{TE^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,\,{\mathbf{x}}^q)}} = D({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{x}}^q) = {\mathrm{sup}}\left\{ {\eta {\mathrm{|}}\left( {{\textstyle{{{\mathbf{x}}^q} \over \eta }}} \right) \in I^q({\mathbf{y}}^q)} \right\}.\)35

    It means that we can alternatively consider distance functions instead of technical efficiency measurements in Section 3.

  16. See Farrell (1957) and Färe and Primont (1995) for more detail.

  17. Formally: \(TE^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{x}}^q) = {\mathrm{max}}_{{\mathbf{w}}^q}{\kern 1pt} CE^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{x}}^q,{\mathbf{w}}^q)\). See also Remarks 3 and 5 in Section 4.

  18. In the same spirit, we could define a lower bound for our technical measurement TE(y, x, w) as: \(TE^l({\mathbf{y}},{\mathbf{x}}) = {\mathrm{min}}\{ TE^1({\mathbf{y}}^1,{\mathbf{x}}^1), \ldots ,TE^Q({\mathbf{y}}^Q,{\mathbf{x}}^Q)\}\).

References

  • Afriat S (1972) Efficiency estimation of production functions. Int Econ Rev 13:568–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banker RD, Maindiratta A (1988) Nonparametric analysis of technical and allocative efficiencies in production. Econometrica 56:1315–1332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banker RD, Morey R (1986) Efficiency analysis for exogenously fixed inputs and outputs. Oper Res 34(4):513–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beasley JE (2003) Allocating fixed costs and resources via data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 147:198–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogetoft P (1996) DEA on relaxed convexity assumptions. Manag Sci 42:457–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves DW, Christensen LR, Diewert WE (1982) The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output and productivity. Econometrica 50:1393–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, De Rock B, Dierynck B, Roodhooft F, Sabbe J (2013) Opening the black box of efficiency measurement: input allocation in multi-output settings. Oper Res 61:1148–1165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, De Rock B, Vermeulen F (2008) Cost-efficient production behavior under economies of scope: a nonparametric methodology. Oper Res 56:204–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, De Rock B, Walheer B (2015) Multi-output efficiency with good and bad outputs. Eur J Oper Res 240:872–881

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, De Rock B, Walheer B (2016) Multi-output profit efficiency and directional distance functions. Omega 61:100–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli TJ, Rao DSP, O’Donnell CJ, Battese GE (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis. Springer, New York

  • Cook WD, Hababou M, Tuenter HJH (2000) Multicomponent efficiency measurement and shared inputs in data envelopment analysis: An application to sales and service performance in bank branches. J Product Anal 14:209–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook WD, Seiford LM (2009) Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA)-thirty years on. Eur J Oper Res 192:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper WW, Seiford LM, Zhu J (2004) Handbook on data envelopment analysis. 2nd edn, Springer, New York

  • Cooper WW, Seiford LM, Tone K (2007) Data envelopment analysis: a comprehensive text with models, applications, references and DEA-solver software. 2nd edn, Springer, New York

  • Debreu G (1951) The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19(3):273–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Despic O, Despic M, Paradi J (2007) DEA-R: ratio-based comparative efficiency model, its mathematical relation to DEA and its use in applications. J Product Anal 28:33–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Parkan C (1983) Linear Programming Tests of Regularity Conditions for Production Functions. In: Eichhorn W, Henn R, Neumann K, Shephard RW (eds) Quantitative Studies on Production and Prices. Physica, Heidelberg

  • Ding J, Dong W, Liang L, Zhu J (2017) Goal congruence analysis in multI-division organizations with shared resources based on data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 263:961–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du J, Cook WD, Liang L, Zhu J (2014) Fixed cost and resource allocation based on DEA cross-efficiency. Eur J Oper Res 235:206–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (1983) Measuring congestion in production. J Econ 43:257–271

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (1985) A nonparametric cost approach to scale efficiency. Scand J Econ 87:594–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2000) Network DEA. Socio-Econ Plan Sci 34:35–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1994) Production frontier. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Norris M, Zhang Z (1994) Productivity growth, technical progress and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am Econ Rev 84:66–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (1995) Non-parametric tests of regularity, farrell efficiency, and goodness of fit. J Econ 69:415–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2004) Modelling undesirable factors in efficiency evaluation: comment. Eur J Oper Res 157:242–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Whittaker G (2007) Network DEA. In: Zhu J, Cook W (eds) Modeling data irregularities and structural complexities in data envelopment analysis, Springer, New York

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Zelenyuk V (2004) Aggregation of cost efficiency: indicators and indexes across firms. Acad Econ Pap 32(3):395–411

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Karagiannis G (2014) A postscript on aggregate Farrell efficiencies. Eur J Oper Res 233:784–786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Karagiannis G (2017) The denominator rule for share-weighting aggregation. Eur J Oper Res 260:1175–1180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Zelenyuk V (2003) On aggregate Farrell efficiencies. Eur J Oper Res 146:615–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Zelenyuk V (2005) On farrell’s decomposition and aggregation. Int J Bus Econ 4(2):167–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Zelenyuk V (2007) Extending Färe and Zelenyuk (2003). Eur J Oper Res 179:594–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Zelenyuk V (2012) Aggregation of scale elasticities across firms. Appl Econ Lett 19:1593–1597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell M (1957) The measurement of productive efficiency. J R Stat Soc Ser 1 120(Part 3):253–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Fried H, Lovell CAK, Schmidt S (2008) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity change. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Hanoch G, Rothschild M (1972) Testing assumptions of production theory: a nonparametric approach. J Political Econ 80:256–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuosmanen T, Cherchye L, Sipilainen T (2006) The law of one price in data envelopment analysis: restricting weight flexibility across firms. Eur J Oper Res 170:735–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li SK, Cheng YS (2007) Solving the puzzles of structural efficiency. Eur J Oper Res 180:713–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li YJ, Yang F, Liang L, Hua ZS (2009) Allocating the fixed cost as a complement of other cost inputs: a DEA approach. Eur J Oper Res 197:389–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmquist S (1953) Index numbers and indifference surfaces. Trab De Estat 4:209–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell M, Whinston D, Green JR (1995) Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer A, Zelenyuk V (2014) Aggregation of Malmquist productivity indexes allowing for reallocation of resources. Eur J Oper Res 238:774–785

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nesterenko V, Zelenyuk V (2007) Measuring potential gains form reallocation of resources. J Product Anal 28:107–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pachkova EV (2009) Restricted reallocation of resources. Eur J Oper Res 196:1049–1057

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen NC (1990) Data envelopment analysis on a relaxed set of assumptions. Manag Sci 36:305–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podinovski VV (2009) Production technologies based on combined proportionality assumptions. J Product Anal 32:21–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podinovski VV, Husain WRW (2017) The hybrid returns-to-scale model and its extension by production trade-offs: an application to the efficiency assessment of public universities in Malaysia. Ann Oper Res 250:65–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podinovski VV, Ismail I, Bouzdine-Chameeva T, Zhang W (2014) Combining the assumptions of variable and constant returns to scale in the efficiency evaluation of secondary schools. Eur J Oper Res 239:504–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podinovski VV, Kuosmanen T (2011) Modelling weak disposability in data envelopment analysis under relaxed convexity assumptions. Eur J Oper Res 211:577–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podinovski VV, Olesen OB, Sarrico SC (2018) Nonparametric production technologies with multiple component processes. Oper Res 66:282–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salerian J, Chan C (2005) Restricting multiple-output multiple-input DEA models by disaggregating the output-input vector. J Product Anal 24:5–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Silva MCA (2018) Output-specific inputs in DEA: an application to courts of justice in Portugal. Omega 79:43–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ten Raa T (2011) Benchmarking and industry performance. J Product Anal 36:285–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tone K, Tsutsui M (2009) Network DEA: a slacks-based measure approach. Eur J Oper Res 197:243–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tulkens H (1993) On FDH analysis: Some methodological issues and applications to retail banking, courts and urban transit. J Product Anal 4:183–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1984) The non-parametric approach to production analysis. Econometrica 52:579–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2016a) A multi-sector nonparametric production-frontier analysis of the economic growth and the convergence of the European countries. Pac Econ Rev 21(4):498–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2016b) Growth and convergence of the OECD countries: a multi-sector production-frontier approach. Eur J Oper Res 252:665–675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2018a) Aggregation of metafrontier technology gap ratios: the case of European sectors in 1995-2015. Eur J Oper Res 269:1013–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2018b) Cost Malmquist productivity index: an output-specific approach for group comparison. J Product Anal 49(1):79–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2018c) Disaggregation of the cost malmquist productivity Index with joint and output-specific inputs. Omega 75:1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walheer B (2018d) Malmquist productivity index for multi-output producers: an application to electricity generation plants. Socio-economic Plann Sci https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2018.02.003

  • Walheer B (2018e) Scale, congestion, and technical efficiency of European countries: a sector-based nonparametric approach. Empir Econ https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1426-7

  • Walheer B (2019) Input allocation in multi-output settings: nonparametric robust efficiency measurements. J Oper Res Soc https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2018.1516175

  • Walheer B, Zhang L-J (2018) Profit Luenberger and Malmquist-Luenberger indexes for multi-activity decision making units: the case of the star-rated hotel industry in China. Tour Manag 69:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu M-M, Chern C-C, Hsiao B (2013) Human resource rightsizing using centralized data envelopment analysis: Evidence from Taiwan’s airports. Omega 41(1):119–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelenyuk V (2006) Aggregation of Malmquist productivity indexes. Eur J Oper Res 174:1076–1086

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelenyuk V (2014) Scale efficiency and homotheticity: equivalence of primal and dual measures. J Product Anal 42:15–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelenyuk V (2015) Aggregation of scale efficiency. Eur J Oper Res 240:269–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the Editor Victor Podinovski, the Associate Editor, and the two anonymous referees for their very productive comments that substantially improved the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Barnabé Walheer.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

The proof is inspired by the proof for the aggregation case provided by Färe et al. (2004), which is itself a particular version of the proof of the aggregation of profit function of Mas-Colell et al. (1995).

A first step is to define the technology at the DMU-level. We impose very weak conditions for that technology set. The only requirement is that the input-output combinations are feasible for all output-specific technologies. Formally, we obtain:

$$T = \left\{ {({\mathbf{x}},{\mathbf{y}}){\mathrm{|}}\forall q \in \{ 1,\, \ldots ,\,Q\} :({\mathbf{x}}^q,\,{\mathbf{y}}^q) \in T^q} \right\}.$$
(72)

In words, x can produce y if, and only if, every output quantity yq can be produced by xq. In a similar vein, we define the DMU-level input requirement set as follows:

$$I({\mathbf{y}}) = \left\{ {{\mathbf{x}}{\mathrm{|}}\forall q \in \left\{ {1,\, \ldots ,\,Q} \right\}:{\mathbf{x}}^q \in I^q\left( {{\mathbf{y}}^q} \right)} \right\}.$$
(73)

Next, we proof that the minimal cost at the DMU-level, denoted by C(y, w), is obtained as the sum of the output-specific minimal costs: \(C({\mathbf{y}},{\mathbf{w}}) = \mathop {\sum}\nolimits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} C^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{w}}^q)\). Note that we assume that the DMU-level actual cost is defined by the sum of the output-specific actual costs, i.e., \(\mathop {\sum}\nolimits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} {\mathbf{w}}^{q{\prime}}{\mathbf{x}}^q\). This holds true for several input types (see Remark 1). The proof contains two steps:

  1. 1.

    For q ∈ {1, …, Q}, let xq ∈ Iq(yq) be arbitrary, then x ∈ I(y) by Eq. (73). By construction, minimal cost at the DMU-level cannot exceed actual cost: \(C({\mathbf{y}},{\mathbf{w}}) \le \mathop {\sum}\nolimits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} {\mathbf{w}}^{q{\prime}}{\mathbf{x}}^q\). As xq for q ∈ {1, …, Q} are arbitrary, we can choose the cost minimizer levels, which gives:

    $$C({\mathbf{y}},{\mathbf{w}}) \le \mathop {\sum}\limits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} C^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{w}}^q).$$
    (74)
  2. 2.

    Let x ∈ I(y) be arbitrary, then there exists, for q ∈ {1, …, Q}, xq ∈ Iq(yq). It follows that: \(\mathop {\sum}\nolimits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} {\mathbf{w}}^{q{\prime}}{\mathbf{x}}^q \ge \mathop {\sum}\nolimits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} C^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{w}}^q)\). As x (and thus xq, \(\forall q\)) is arbitrary, we can choose the cost minimizer levels, which gives:

$$C({\mathbf{y}},{\mathbf{w}}) \ge \mathop {\sum}\limits_{q = 1}^Q {\kern 1pt} C^q({\mathbf{y}}^q,{\mathbf{w}}^q).$$
(75)

Combining the two previous equations end the proof.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Walheer, B. Disaggregation for efficiency analysis. J Prod Anal 51, 137–151 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-019-00546-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-019-00546-9

Keywords

Navigation