Log in

Information services and omnichannel retailing strategy choices of e-commerce platforms with supplier competition

  • Published:
Electronic Commerce Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The integration of offline channels and online channels has become a direction for the transformation and development of many e-commerce platforms, so omnichannel retailing has become an important strategy. Thus, we build a theoretical model between a platform and two suppliers to study the platform’s optimal information service and omnichannel strategy choice (under a reselling agreement vs. under a hybrid retailing agreement). The results show that when the product competition intensity is low, an omnichannel strategy under a reselling agreement is conducive to increasing the offline information service level and profits of the platform. When the product competition intensity is high, the omnichannel strategy under a hybrid retailing agreement is the optimal choice, and the platform can set a smaller referral fee to transfer part of the profit to suppliers to encourage suppliers to enter omnichannel retailing. Furthermore, the platform can improve the information service level using new retailing technology, which can create a higher product showrooming effect. Finally, we introduce the case of China’s household appliances to verify the effectiveness of our research and suggest that the platform establishes experience stores that can weaken the competitive relationship between suppliers and the platform to achieve a win–win strategy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source: http://www.sohu.com/a/354770001_339728, http://news.iresearch.cn/yx/2019/11/307330.shtml.

  2. Source:https://istore.tmall.com/index.htm, https://www.hishop.com.cn/tags/15383.html.

  3. Source: https://www.xinlingshou.cn/index.htm.

  4. Source: https://xw.qq.com/amphtml/20210107A0408F00.

  5. The product showrooming effect is generated during the experience of the store’s product display, driven by consumers’ experiential purchase behaviours, with positive impacts on product demand [28].

  6. According to the operations and marketing literature [32, 42], The cost of information service can usually be set as \(f(s_{A} ) = ks_{A}^{2} /2\), where k is a positive cost coefficient and refers to the cost differences in service effort across different product categories. For analytical tractability and exclusion of some trivial cases, we follow Li et al. [28] and Chen [5] to assume that \(k = 1\) in this study.

References

  1. Balaji, M. S., & Roy, S. K. (2017). Value co-creation with Internet of things technology in the retail industry. Journal of Marketing Management, 33(1–2), 7–31.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Bell, D., Gallino, S., & Moreno, A. (2015). Showrooms and information provision in omni-channel retail. Production and Operations Management, 24(3), 360–362.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Bell, D., Gallino, S., & Moreno, A. (2017). Offline showrooms in omnichannel retail: Demand and operational benefits. Management Science, 64(4), 1629–1651.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Brynjolfsson, E., Hu, Y. J., & Rahman, M. S. (2013). Competing in the age of omnichannel retailing. MIT Sloan Management Review, 54(4), 23–29.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Chen, F. (2005). Salesforce incentives, market information, and production/inventory planning. Management Science, 51(1), 60–75.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Choi, S. C. (1991). Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. Marketing science, 10(4), 271–296.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Choi, S. C. (1996). Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel. Journal of Retailing, 72(2), 117–134.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Chopra, S. (2018). The evolution of omni-channel retailing and its impact on supply chains. Transportation Research Procedia, 30, 4–13.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Fang, F., Gurnani, H., & Natarajan, H. P. (2018). Leadership, dominance, and preeminence in a channel structure with a common retailer. Decision Sciences, 49(1), 65–120.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Gallino, S., & Moreno, A. (2018). The value of fit information in online retail: Evidence from a randomized field experiment. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 20(4), 767–787.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Gao, F., & Su, X. (2016). Omnichannel retail operations with buy-online-and-pick-up-in-store. Management Science, 63(8), 2478–2492.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Gao, F., & Su, X. (2017). Online and offline information for omni-channel retailing. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 19(1), 84–98.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Garcıa-Gallego, A., & Georgantzıs, N. (2001). Multiproduct activity in an experimental differentiated oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(3–4), 493–518.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Geng, X., Tan, Y., & Wei, L. (2018). How add-on pricing interacts with distribution contracts. Production and Operations Management, 27(4), 605–623.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Gupta, V. K., Ting, Q. U., & Tiwari, M. K. (2019). Multi-period price optimization problem for omni-channel retailers accounting for customer heterogeneity. International Journal of Production Economics, 212, 155–167.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Gu, Z., & Tayi, G. K. (2017). Consumer pseudo-showrooming and omni-channel product placement strategies. Management Information Systems Quarterly, 41(2), 583–606.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Hagiu, A., & Wright, J. (2014). Marketplace or reseller? Management Science, 61(1), 184–203.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Hagiu, A., & Wright, J. (2015). Multi-sided platforms. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 43(10), 162–174.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Harsha, P., Subramanian, S., & Ettl, M. (2019). A practical price optimization approach for omnichannel retailing. INFORMS Journal on Optimization, 1(3), 241–264.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Hu, F., & Zhou, Z. (2020). Monopoly or competition: Strategic analysis of a retailing technology service provision. Electronic Commerce Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-020-09426-z

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Huang, M., & **, D. (2020). Impact of buy-online-and-return-in-store service on omnichannel retailing: A supply chain competitive perspective. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.elerap.2020.100977

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Huang, T. L. (2019). Psychological mechanisms of brand love and information technology identity in virtual retail environments. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 47, 251–264.

    Google Scholar 

  23. **, D., Caliskan-Demirag, O., Chen, F. Y., & Huang, M. (2020). Omnichannel retailers’ return policy strategies in the presence of competition. International Journal of Production Economics. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.107595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. **g, B. (2018). Showrooming and webrooming: Information externalities between online and offline sellers. Marketing Science, 37(3), 469–483.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Kim, J. C., & Chun, S. H. (2018). Cannibalization and competition effects on a manufacturer’s retail channel strategies: Implications on an omni-channel business model. Decision Support Systems, 109, 5–14.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Kong, R., Luo, L., Chen, L., & Keblis, M. F. (2020). The effects of BOPS implementation under different pricing strategies in omnichannel retailing. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 141, 102014. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2020.102014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Kuksov, D., & Liao, C. (2018). When showrooming increases retailer profit. Journal of Marketing Research, 55(4), 459–473.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Li, G., Li, L., & Sun, J. (2019). Pricing and service effort strategy in a dual-channel supply chain with showrooming effect. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 126, 32–48.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Li, M., Zhang, X., & Dan, B. (2020). Competition and cooperation in a supply chain with an offline showroom under asymmetric information. International Journal of Production Research, 58(19), 5964–5979.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Li, G., Zhang, T., & Tayi, G. K. (2020). Inroad into omni-channel retailing: Physical showroom deployment of an online retailer. European Journal of Operational Research, 283(2), 676–691.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Li, L., & Zhang, H. (2008). Confidentiality and information sharing in supply chain coordination. Management science, 54(8), 1467–1481.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Liu, W., Liu, Y., Zhu, D., Wang, Y., & Liang, Z. (2016). The influences of demand disruption on logistics service supply chain coordination: A comparison of three coordination modes. International Journal of Production Economics, 179, 59–76.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Morrison, G., & Marcotte, D. (2019). Looking to the future of commerce: Retail transformation as connected consumers embrace smart homes and smart stores. Journal of Brand Strategy, 8(3), 241–249.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Pantano, E., & Timmermans, H. (2014). What is smart for retailing? Procedia Environmental Sciences, 22, 101–107.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Pantano, E., & Vannucci, V. (2019). Who is innovating? An exploratory research of digital technologies diffusion in retail industry. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 49, 297–304.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Park, J., Dayarian, I., & Montreuil, B. (2021). Showcasing optimization in omnichannel retailing. European Journal of Operational Research, 294(3), 895–905.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Piotrowicz, W., & Cuthbertson, R. (2014). Introduction to the special issue information technology in retail: Toward omnichannel retailing. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 18(4), 5–16.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Rigby, D. (2011). The future of shop**. Harvard Business Review, 89(12), 65–76.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Song, P., Wang, Q., Liu, H., & Li, Q. (2020). The value of buy-online-and-pickup-in-store in omni-channel: Evidence from customer usage data. Production and Operations Management, 29(4), 995–1010.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Tan, Y., & Carrillo, J. E. (2017). Strategic analysis of the agency model for digital goods. Production and Operations Management, 26(4), 724–741.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Tian, L., Vakharia, A. J., Tan, Y., & Xu, Y. (2018). Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid: Strategic analysis of an emerging e-commerce model. Production and Operations Management, 27(8), 1595–1610.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Tsay, A. A., & Agrawal, N. (2004). Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 93–110.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Verhoef, P. C., Kannan, P. K., & Inman, J. J. (2015). From multi-channel retailing to omni-channel retailing. Journal of Retailing, 91(2), 174–181.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Wei, Y., & Li, F. (2020). Omnichannel supply chain operations for luxury products with conspicuous consumers. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2020.101918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Zhang, T., Li, G., Cheng, T. C. E., & Shum, S. (2020). Consumer inter-product showrooming and information service provision in an omni-channel supply chain. Decision Sciences, 51(5), 1232–1264.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Zhang, S., & Zhang, J. (2020). Agency selling or reselling: E-tailer information sharing with supplier offline entry. European Journal of Operational Research, 280(1), 134–151.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Zhu, C., & Yao, Z. (2018). Comparison between the agency and wholesale model under the e-book duopoly market. Electronic Commerce Research, 18(2), 313–337.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The research described in this paper was substantially supported by China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (Grant No. 2019M652682), Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Grant No. CCNU20QN016).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhenglong Zhou.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

According to (8), we have

$$ \frac{{\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset } }}{\partial \gamma } = \frac{{\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset } }}{\partial \gamma } = \frac{1}{{(2 - \gamma )^{3} }} $$
(51)
$$ \frac{{\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } }}{\partial \gamma } = \frac{4 - 3\gamma }{{2(1 - \gamma )^{2} (2 - \gamma )^{3} }} $$
(52)

Since \(0 < \gamma < 1\), we verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\), and \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\). That is, the equilibrium profits (\(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset }\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset }\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\)) for the supply chain members increase with the increase of the competition intensity (\(\gamma\)) between two products. Q.E.D.

1.2 Proof of Lemma 1

Under the reselling agreement, if the platform establishes an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing, we can obtain the equilibrium profits for the suppliers and platform respectively are \(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\). In order to ensure these equilibrium results are non-negative, we need \(\Phi = 2(1 - \gamma^{2} ) - \alpha (\alpha + \beta \gamma ) - \beta (\beta + \alpha \gamma ) > 0\), i.e., \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\). For obtaining the threshold \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\), we solve the equation \((1 - \gamma^{2} ) - \alpha (\alpha + \beta \gamma ) - \beta (\beta + \alpha \gamma ) = 0\) and have

$$ \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta ) = \frac{{\sqrt {\alpha^{2} \beta^{2} + 2(2 - \alpha^{2} - \beta^{2} )} - \alpha \beta }}{2} $$
(53)

Q.E.D.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 2

When \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\), We verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \gamma > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \gamma > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \gamma > 0\). That is, the equilibrium profits (\(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\)) for the supply chain members increase with the increase of the competition intensity \(\gamma\).

Next, we discuss the impact of \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\) on the equilibrium profits (\(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\)). Due to the complicated calculation process, we draw on the proof process of Tian et al. [10] to prove the equilibrium profits (\(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\)) for the supply chain members increase with the increase of the product showrooming effect \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\). We first examine the limiting situation (\(\gamma = 0\) and \(\gamma = \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\)), and then complete the proof using a continuity argument.

When \(\gamma = 0\), we obtain (53) according to (18).

$$ \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \frac{{\left\{ \begin{gathered} [2(8 - 4\alpha^{2} ) + (8\alpha - 2\alpha^{3} - 4)\beta + (6\alpha^{2} - 32)\beta^{2} + (\alpha^{3} - 4\alpha + 2)\beta^{3} + \hfill \\ (12 - \alpha^{2} )\beta^{4} ] \times [(8 - 4\alpha^{2} ) + (2 - \alpha^{3} )\beta + (4 + \alpha^{2} )\beta^{2} ] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\}}}{{2(2 - \alpha^{2} - \beta^{2} )[16 - 8\alpha^{2} + (3\alpha^{2} - 8)\beta^{2} ]^{2} }} $$
(54)

We verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\), and have \(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\exists \alpha \in [0,1]} } \right. \le \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\alpha = 1} } \right.\). Further, when \(\gamma = 0\), we obtain (55) according to (19).

$$ \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \frac{{\left\{ \begin{gathered} \left[ {2\left( {8 - 4\beta^{2} } \right) - \left( {4 - 8\beta + 2\beta^{3} } \right)\alpha - \left( {32 - 6\beta^{2} } \right)\alpha^{2} + \left( {2 - 4\beta + \beta^{3} } \right)\alpha^{3} + } \right. \hfill \\ \left. {\left( {12 - \beta^{2} } \right)\alpha^{4} ] \times [\left( {8 - 4\beta^{2} } \right) + \left( {2 - \beta^{3} } \right)\alpha + \left( {4 + \beta^{2} } \right)\alpha^{2} } \right] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\}}}{{2\left( {2 - \alpha^{2} - \beta^{2} } \right)\left[ {16 - 8\beta^{2} + \left( {3\beta^{2} - 8} \right)\alpha^{2} } \right]^{2} }} $$
(55)

Then, we verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\), and have \(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\exists \alpha \in [0,1]} } \right. \le \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\alpha = 1} } \right.\). Similar, we verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\exists \alpha \in [0,1]} } \right. \le \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \left| {_{\alpha = 1} } \right.\).

When \(\gamma = \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\), we verify that \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\), \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \alpha > 0\), and \(\partial \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} /\partial \beta > 0\) in the same manner. Thus, according to the continuity argument, if \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\), the equilibrium profits (\(\hat{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\hat{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\)) for the supply chain members increase with the increase of the intra-product showrooming effect \(\alpha\), and the product showrooming effect \(\beta\). Q.E.D.

1.4 Proof of Proposition 3

According to (27), we have

$$ \frac{{\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset } }}{\partial \gamma } = \frac{{\left[ {2 + (1 - \theta )\gamma - \theta \gamma^{2} } \right]\left[ {8(1 - \theta ) + 12(1 - \theta )\gamma - (4 - 2\theta - 2\theta^{2} )\gamma^{3} - (1 - \theta^{2} )\gamma^{4} } \right]}}{{2\left[ {8 - \left( {6 + 2\theta } \right)\gamma^{2} + (1 + \theta )\gamma^{4} } \right]}} $$
(56)
$$ \frac{{\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset } }}{\partial \gamma } = \frac{{\left\{ \begin{gathered} (1 - \theta )[8 + 6\gamma - (3 + \theta )\gamma^{2} - (2 + \theta )\gamma^{3} ] \times \hfill \\ [48 + (48 + 32\theta )\gamma - (1 + \theta )(12\gamma^{2} + 32\gamma^{3} ) - (6 + 8\theta + 2\theta^{2} )(\gamma^{4} - \gamma^{5} ) + (2 + 3\theta + \theta^{2} )\gamma^{6} ] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\}}}{{2[8 - (6 + 2\theta )\gamma^{2} + (1 + \theta )\gamma^{4} ]^{3} }} $$
(57)

Since \(0 < \gamma < 1\), \(\theta \in [0.05,0.25]\), we verify that

$$ 2 + (1 - \theta )\gamma - \theta \gamma^{2} > 0,8(1 - \theta ) + 12(1 - \theta )\gamma - (4 - 2\theta - 2\theta^{2} )\gamma^{3} - (1 - \theta^{2} )\gamma^{4} > 0 $$
(58)
$$ 8 - (6 + 2\theta )\gamma^{2} + (1 + \theta )\gamma^{4} > 0,8 + 6\gamma - (3 + \theta )\gamma^{2} - (2 + \theta )\gamma^{3} > 0 $$
(59)
$$ 48 + (48 + 32\theta )\gamma - (1 + \theta )(12\gamma^{2} + 32\gamma^{3} ) - (6 + 8\theta + 2\theta^{2} )(\gamma^{4} - \gamma^{5} ) + (2 + 3\theta + \theta^{2} )\gamma^{6} > 0 $$
(60)

Thus, we have \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\), \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\). Then, we verify that \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } /\partial \gamma > 0\) in the same manner. That is, the equilibrium profits (\(\tilde{\Pi }_{A}^{\emptyset }\),\(\tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{\emptyset }\), and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\)) for the supply chain members increase with the increase of the competition intensity (\(\gamma\)) between two products. Q.E.D.

1.5 Proof of Lemma 2

Under the hybrid retailing agreement, if the platform establish an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing strategy and supplier B does not enter the omni-channel retailing, we can obtain the equilibrium profits for the suppliers and platform respectively are \(\tilde{\Pi }_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}}\),\(\tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\). In order to ensure these equilibrium results are non-negative, we need \(H_{0}^{*} = [4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} -\) \(8\alpha^{2} + 2\theta \alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} > 0\). Thus, we set \([4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} - 8\alpha^{2} + 2\theta \alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} = 0\) and get the positive roots as

$$ \tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta ) = \sqrt {\frac{{\left( {8 + 8\theta - 2\theta \alpha^{2} } \right) - \sqrt {\left( {8 + 8\theta - 2\theta \alpha^{2} } \right)^{2} - 4(1 + \theta )^{2} (16 - 8\alpha^{2} )} }}{{2(1 + \theta )^{2} }}} $$
(61)
$$ \tilde{\gamma }_{2} (\alpha ,\theta ) = \sqrt {\frac{{(8 + 8\theta - 2\theta \alpha^{2} ) + \sqrt {(8 + 8\theta - 2\theta \alpha^{2} )^{2} - 4(1 + \theta )^{2} (16 - 8\alpha^{2} )} }}{{2(1 + \theta )^{2} }}} $$
(62)

\(\tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta ) < \tilde{\gamma }_{2} (\alpha ,\theta )\), we verify that \(\partial \tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta )/\partial \alpha < 0\), \(\partial \tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta )/\partial \theta < 0\), \(\partial \tilde{\gamma }_{2} (\alpha ,\theta )/\partial \alpha < 0\), \(\partial \tilde{\gamma }_{2} (\alpha ,\theta )/\partial \theta < 0\). That is, in the condition of \(\theta \in [0.05,0.25]\) and \(0 < \alpha \le 1\), the minimum positive root of \([4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} - 8\alpha^{2} + 2\theta \alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} = 0\) is \(\tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta )\left| {_{\theta = 0.25,\alpha = 1} } \right.\). We calculate that \(\tilde{\gamma }_{1} (\alpha ,\theta )\left| {_{\theta = 0.25,\alpha = 1} } \right. = 1.0049 > 1\). Thus, the equilibrium results are always non-negative in the condition of \(0 < \gamma < 1\), \(\theta \in [0.05,0.25]\), and \(0 \le \alpha \le 1\). Q.E.D.

1.6 Proof of Lemma 3

Under the hybrid retailing agreement, if the platform establish an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing strategy and supplier B enters the omni-channel retailing, we can obtain the equilibrium profits for the suppliers and platform respectively are \(\tilde{\Pi }_{A}^{OE}\),\(\tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{OE}\) and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\). In order to ensure these equilibrium results are non-negative, we need \(H_{0} = [4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} -\) \(2[(1 + \theta )\beta \gamma + 2\alpha ](2a + \beta \gamma - \theta \gamma \beta - \alpha \theta \gamma^{2} ) - 2\theta (2\beta + a\gamma )^{2} > 0\). Similar to the proof of Lemma 2, we get

$$ H_{0} = (16 - 4\theta \beta - 8\alpha^{2} ) - 8\alpha \beta \gamma + [4\alpha^{2} \theta - 2(1 - \theta^{2} )\beta^{2} - 2\alpha \theta - 8(1 + \theta )]\gamma^{2} + 2\alpha \beta \theta (1 + \theta )\gamma^{3} + (1 + \theta )^{2} \gamma^{4} $$
(63)
$$ \frac{{\partial H_{0} }}{\partial \gamma } = - 8\alpha \beta + 2[4\alpha^{2} \theta - 2(1 - \theta^{2} )\beta^{2} - 2\alpha \theta - 8(1 + \theta )]\gamma + 6\alpha \beta \theta (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} + 4(1 + \theta )^{2} \gamma^{3} < 0 $$
(64)

Due to the complicated calculation process, we draw on the proof process of Tian et al. [41] to prove that the equilibrium results are non-negative if and only if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\). We first examine the limiting situation (\(\gamma = 0\) and \(\gamma = 1\)), and then complete the proof using a continuity argument.

When \(\gamma = 0\), we have \(H_{0} = (16 - 4\theta \beta - 8\alpha^{2} ) > 0\), i.e., the equilibrium results are always non-negative in the condition of \(\gamma = 0\), \(\theta \in [0.05,0.25]\), and \(0 \le \alpha \le 1\), \(0 \le \beta \le \alpha\). When \(\gamma = 1\), we have \(H_{0} = 8 + 4\alpha^{2} \theta + 2\alpha \beta \theta (1 + \theta ) + (1 + \theta )^{2} - 4\theta \beta - 8\alpha^{2} - 8\alpha \beta - 2(1 - \theta^{2} )\beta^{2} - 2\alpha \theta - 8\theta\), and get

$$ \left\{ \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial H_{0} }}{\partial \alpha } = - 8\alpha (2 - \theta ) - 2\theta (1 - \beta - \theta \beta ) - 8\beta < 0 \hfill \\ \frac{{\partial H_{0} }}{\partial \beta } = - 2\theta (2 - \alpha - \alpha \theta ) - 2(1 - \theta^{2} ) - 8\alpha < 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right. $$
(65)

According to (65), we have \(H_{0} > H_{0} \left| {_{\alpha = 1,\beta = 1} } \right.\), where \(H_{0} \left| {_{\alpha = 1,\beta = 1} } \right. = - \theta (6 - \theta ) - 9 < 0\). According to the continuity argument, \(\exists \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta ) > 0\), if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\), we have \(H_{0} > 0\); if \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta ) < \gamma < 1\), we have \(H_{0} < 0\). Thus, under the hybrid retailing agreement, if the platform establish an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing strategy and supplier B enters the omni-channel retailing, the equilibrium results are non-negative if and only if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\). Q.E.D.

1.7 Proof of Proposition 4

Under the reselling agreement, suppliers cannot make the decision to enter the platform’s omni-channel retailing. Under the hybrid retailing agreement, we have

$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{{OE}} - \tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\bar{E}}} = \frac{{1 - \theta }}{{[4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma ^{2} ]^{2} H_{0} ^{2} H_{0}^{{*2}} }} \times \left\{ \begin{gathered} H_{0}^{{*2}} \left[ {(2 + \gamma )H_{0} + HH_{5} + (\gamma H_{0} - H_{5} H_{{00}} )\tilde{w}_{A}^{{OE}} } \right]^{2} - \hfill \\ H_{0} ^{2} \left[ {(2 + \gamma )H_{0}^{*} + \alpha \gamma H^{*} + \left( {\gamma H_{0}^{*} - \alpha \gamma H_{{00}}^{*} } \right)\tilde{w}_{A}^{{O\bar{E}}} } \right]^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\} - F $$
(66)

Thus, if and only if \(F < \tilde{F}(\alpha ,\beta ,\gamma ) = \frac{{(1 - \theta )\left\{ \begin{gathered} H_{0}^{*2} [(2 + \gamma )H_{0} + HH_{5} + (\gamma H_{0} - H_{5} H_{00} )\tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} ]^{2} - \hfill \\ H_{0}^{2} \left[ {(2 + \gamma )H_{0}^{*} + \alpha \gamma H^{*} + (\gamma H_{0}^{*} - \alpha \gamma H_{00}^{*} )\tilde{w}_{A}^{{O\overline{E}}} } \right]^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\}}}{{[4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} H_{0}^{2} H_{0}^{*2} }}\), we can get \(\tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{OE} - \tilde{\Pi }_{B}^{{O\overline{E}}} > 0\), i.e., supplier B will choose to enter the omni-channel retailing. Further, in order to ensure \(\tilde{F}(\alpha ,\beta ,\gamma )\) is non-negative, we need \(H_{0} > 0\) and \(H_{0}^{*} > 0\). According to Lemma 2 and Lemma 3, we have the constraint of \(H_{0} > 0\) and \(H_{0}^{*} > 0\) is \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\). Therefore, under the hybrid retailing agreement, when the platform establishes an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing strategy, supplier B will choose to enter the omni-channel retailing if and only if \(F < \tilde{F}(\alpha ,\beta ,\gamma )\) and \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\alpha ,\beta )\). Q.E.D.

1.8 Proof of Proposition 5

Under the reselling agreement, suppliers cannot make the decision to enter the platform’s omni-channel retailing. Thus, the platform’s omni-channel retailing decision is not affected by two suppliers. Under the hybrid retailing agreement, we get \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} /\partial \gamma > 0\) in Lemma 3. Therefore, we will first examine the limiting situation \(\gamma = 0\) and \(\gamma = 1\), and then complete the proof using a continuity argument.

When \(\gamma = 0\), we obtain formula (67) according to formula (49).

$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} = \frac{{(2 + \theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }}{{16(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} + \frac{{\theta (8 + 4\beta + 2\theta \beta^{2} - 10\theta \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{64(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} - \frac{{(2 + 3\theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} - 2\theta^{2} \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{8(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} $$
(67)

We verify that \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} /\partial \beta > 0\) for \(\forall \beta \in [0,1]\), so we have \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} \left| {_{\beta = 0} } \right. \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} \left| {_{\beta \in [0,1]} } \right.\). Because of the continuity argument, we have \(\exists \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) > 0\), if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\), there is \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\), that is, the platform’s omni-channel retailing under the hybrid retailing agreement is better off with supplier B’s entry when \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\).

When \(\gamma = 1\) and \(\theta = 0.1\), we have \(H_{1} = 2 + 1.1\beta\), \(H_{2} = 2.8\),\(H_{3} = 1.9 + 0.9\beta\), \(H_{4} = 3.1\), \(H_{5} = 1 + 2\beta\), \(H = 12.09 + 7.07\beta\), \(H_{0} = 0.61 - 8.58\beta - 2.78\beta^{2}\), \(H_{00} = 3.51 + 1.51\beta\), then we get

$$ \tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} = \frac{{24.679 - 0.29\beta - 1.421\beta^{2} }}{{14.558 - 5.104\beta - 2.842\beta^{2} }} $$
(68)
$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} = \left\{ \begin{gathered} \frac{{3.1H_{0} + HH_{1} + [2H_{0} - H_{1} H_{00} - 4H_{0} + 1.1H_{0} ]\tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} }}{{8.41(0.61 - 8.58\beta - 2.78\beta^{2} )}} \times \hfill \\ \frac{{2.8H_{0} + HH_{3} - [H_{0} + (1.9 + 0.9\beta )H_{00} ]\tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} }}{{8.41(0.61 - 8.58\beta - 2.78\beta^{2} )}} \hfill \\ + \frac{{0.1[3H_{0} + (1 + 2\beta )H + H_{0} - H_{00} - 2\beta H_{00} )\tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} ]^{2} }}{{70.73(0.61 - 8.58\beta - 2.78\beta^{2} )^{2} }} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\} - \frac{{(H - H_{00} \tilde{w}_{A}^{OE} )^{2} }}{{2H_{0}^{2} }} $$
(69)

According to (69), we have \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) when \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(0 < \beta < \tilde{\beta }^{*}\), that is, the platform’s omni-channel retailing under the hybrid retailing agreement is better off with supplier B’s entry when \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(0 < \beta < \tilde{\beta }^{*}\)(as illustrated in Fig. 7b); \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} > \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) when \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(\tilde{\beta }^{*} < \beta \le 1\), i.e., the platform’s omni-channel retailing under the hybrid retailing agreement is worse off with supplier B’s entry when \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(\tilde{\beta }^{*} < \beta \le 1\). Q.E.D.

1.9 Proof of Proposition 6 and Corollary 1

According to Lemma 1, we have \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \frac{{\sqrt {2 - \beta^{2} } - \beta }}{2}\), and the equilibrium profit \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\) is non-negative if and only if \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\). When \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\), we verify that \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} > \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\); \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\), we verify that \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\).This concludes the proof of Proposition 6.

Further, we verify that \(\partial \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )/\partial \beta < 0\), and thus have \(\min \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\left| {_{\beta = 1} } \right. = 0\), \(\max \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\left| {_{\beta = 0} } \right. = 0.707\). Based on the results of \(\min \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\) and \(\max \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\), we get \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < 0\) and \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } > 0\) when \(0.7 < \gamma < 1\).that is, when \(0.7 < \gamma < 1\), the platform will not establish an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing strategy.

When \(0 < \gamma < 0.7\), we verify that if \(0 \le \beta < \hat{\beta }^{*}\), have \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} > \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\), i.e., the platform will establish an experience store to open an omni-channel retailing strategy. Where, \(\hat{\beta }^{*}\) can be obtained by solve the equation \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \gamma\). If \(0 < \gamma < 0.7\) and \(\hat{\beta }^{*} < \beta \le 1\), have \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\), i.e., the platform will not establish an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing strategy. This concludes the proof of Corollary 1. Q.E.D.

1.10 Proof of Proposition 7

According to Lemma 3 and proposition 5, we get \(\partial \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} /\partial \gamma > 0\) under the hybrid retailing agreement, and when \(\gamma = 0\), we obtain

$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} = \frac{{(2 + \theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }}{{16(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} + \frac{{\theta (8 + 4\beta + 2\theta \beta^{2} - 10\theta \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{64(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} - \frac{{(2 + 3\theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} - 2\theta^{2} \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{8(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} $$
(70)
$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \frac{1}{4} + \frac{\theta }{4} - \frac{1}{8},\quad \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } = \frac{1}{16} + \frac{\theta }{4} $$
(71)

We verify that \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) for \(\forall \beta \in [0,1]\). Because of the continuity argument, we have \(\exists \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) > 0\), if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\), there is \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\), that is, the platform always establishes an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing with or without supplier entry when \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\).

When \(\gamma = 1\) and \(\theta = 0.1\), we have \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} = 4.143\), \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } = 0.537\) according to (68) and (69), thus, \(\exists \tilde{\beta }^{*} > 0\), if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\) and \(0 \le \beta < \tilde{\beta }^{*}\), we get \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\). That is, the platform always establishes an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing with or without supplier entry. When \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\), \(\tilde{\beta }^{*} < \beta \le 1\), we get \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), i.e., the platform establishes an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing if and only if there is no supplier entry. Q.E.D.

1.11 Proof of Proposition 8

According to Formulas (8) and (28), we have

$$ \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } - \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } = \left\{ \begin{gathered} \frac{1}{{2(1 - \gamma )(2 - \gamma )^{2} }} - \frac{{[2 + \gamma (1 + \theta ) - 2\tilde{w}_{A}^{\emptyset } + \gamma^{2} (1 + \theta )\tilde{w}_{A}^{\emptyset } ][2 + \gamma - \theta \gamma (1 + \gamma )]}}{{2[4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} }} - \hfill \\ \frac{{\theta [(2 + \gamma )(4 - 2\gamma^{2} + \gamma ) - \theta \gamma^{2} (1 + \gamma )]^{2} }}{{4[4 - (1 + \theta )\gamma^{2} ]^{2} (2 - \gamma^{2} )^{2} }} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right\} $$
(72)

where \(\tilde{w}_{A}^{\emptyset } = \frac{2 + \gamma - \theta \gamma (1 + \gamma )}{{2(2 - \gamma^{2} )}}\). Further, Propositions 1 and 3 show that the equilibrium profit \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\) under the reselling agreement increases with the increase of the product competition intensity \(\gamma\); under the hybrid retailing agreement, the equilibrium profit \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset }\) increases with the increase of the product competition intensity \(\gamma\). Thus, we can use a continuity argument to prove Proposition 8. When \(\gamma = 0\), we have \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } - \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } = \frac{1}{16} - \frac{\theta }{4}\), and since \(\theta \in [0.05,0.25]\), we verify that \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } - \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } \ge 0\). When \(\gamma \to 1\), we verify that \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } - \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{\emptyset } > 0\) for \(\forall \theta \in [0.05,0.25]\). Because of the continuity argument, we get the platform’s optimal strategic choice is reselling agreement when he does not establish an experience store to open the omni-channel retailing. Q.E.D.

1.12 Proof of Proposition 9

According to Proposition 2, Lemmas 2 and 3, we show that the equilibrium profit \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\) and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) increases with the increase of the product competition intensity \(\gamma\). Thus, we can use a continuity argument to prove Proposition 9.

When \(\gamma = 0\), we have Formula (73) based on Formulas (20). i.e.,

$$ \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \left[ \begin{gathered} \frac{{(8 + 4\beta - 12\beta^{2} - 2\beta^{3} + 4\beta^{4} )^{2} + (4 + 10\beta - 2\beta^{2} - 6\beta^{3} )(4 - 10\beta - 10\beta^{2} - 7\beta^{3} + 5\beta^{4} )}}{{(2 - 2\beta^{2} )^{2} (8 - 5\beta^{2} )^{2} }} \hfill \\ - \frac{{(8 + 8\beta - 10\beta^{2} - 4\beta^{3} + 2\beta^{4} )(8 + 8\beta - 10\beta^{2} - 4\beta^{3} + 2\beta^{4} )}}{{2(2 - 2\beta^{2} )^{2} (8 - 5\beta^{2} )^{2} }} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right] $$
(73)

According to Formulas (39) and (49), we have \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} = \frac{1}{8} + \frac{\theta }{4}\), and get

$$ \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} = \frac{{(2 + \theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }}{{16(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} + \frac{{\theta (8 + 4\beta + 2\theta \beta^{2} - 10\theta \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{64(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} - \frac{{(2 + 3\theta \beta - \theta \beta^{2} - 2\theta^{2} \beta^{3} )^{2} }}{{8(1 - \theta \beta^{2} )(2 - \theta \beta^{2} )^{2} }} $$
(74)

We verify that \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} < \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\) for \(\forall \beta \in [0,1]\). Further, according to Lemma 1, we have \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \frac{{\sqrt {2 - \beta^{2} } - \beta }}{2}\), and the equilibrium profit \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\) is non-negative if and only if \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\). In order to ensure \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) = \frac{{\sqrt {2 - \beta^{2} } - \beta }}{2} > 0\), we need \(0 < \beta < \hat{\beta }^{*} < 1\). According to Lemma 3, we have the equilibrium profit \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\) and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) is non-negative if and only if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\). We verify that \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\) for \(\forall \beta \in [0,1]\). Thus, because of the continuity argument, we have \(\exists \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) > 0\) and \(0 < \hat{\beta }^{*} < 1\), if \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\) and \(0 < \beta < \hat{\beta }^{*}\), there is \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE} < \hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}}\), i.e., the platform’s optimal strategic choice is reselling agreement. When \(0 < \gamma < \hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\) and \(\hat{\beta }^{*} < \beta < \min (\tilde{\beta }^{*} ,1)\), there is \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} \le \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\), i.e., the platform’s optimal strategic choice is hybrid retailing agreement with supplier entry;

When \(\gamma = 1\), we have \(\hat{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < 0\). Furthermore, according to Proposition 5, we have if \(0 < \gamma < \tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta )\), there is \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\); if \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(0 < \beta < \tilde{\beta }^{*}\), there is \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} < \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) (as illustrated in Fig. 7b); and \(\tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{{O\overline{E}}} > \tilde{\Pi }_{P}^{OE}\) when \(\tilde{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(\tilde{\beta }^{*} < \beta \le 1\). Therefore, because of the continuity argument, we have if \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(0 < \beta < \tilde{\beta }^{*}\), the platform’s optimal strategic choice is hybrid retailing agreement with supplier entry; if \(\hat{\gamma }^{*} (\beta ) < \gamma < 1\) and \(\tilde{\beta }^{*} < \beta < 1\), the platform’s optimal strategic choice is hybrid retailing agreement without supplier entry. Q.E.D.

Appendix 2

See Tables 4 and 5.

Table 4 The expressions of \(H^{*}\), \(H_{0}^{*}\) and \(H_{00}^{*}\)
Table 5 The expressions of \(H\), \(H_{0}^{{}}\) and \(H_{00}^{{}}\)(including \(H_{1}\) to \(H_{5}\))

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hu, F., Zhou, Z. Information services and omnichannel retailing strategy choices of e-commerce platforms with supplier competition. Electron Commer Res 23, 2647–2689 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-022-09557-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-022-09557-5

Keywords

Navigation