Log in

Portfolio optimization under Solvency II

  • S.I.: Risk in Financial Economics
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the current low interest-rate and highly-regulated environment investing capital efficiently is one of the most important challenges insurance companies face. Certain quantitative parts of regulatory requirements (e.g. Solvency II capital requirements) result in constraints on the investment strategies. This paper mathematically describes the implications of Solvency II constraints on the investment strategies of insurance companies in an expected utility framework with a focus on the market risk module. For this constrained expected utility problem, we define a two-step approach that leads to closed-form approximations for the optimal investment strategies. This proposal circumvents the technical difficulties encountered when applying the convex duality approach or the theory of viscosity solutions. The investment strategies found using the two-step approach can be understood as the optimal investment strategies for constraint problems according to Solvency II. The impact of such constraints on the asset allocation and the performance of these strategies is assessed in a numerical case study.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note, that even though the interest-rate r and the liabilities L are assumed to be constant, Solvency II regulators force interest-rate risk constraints on the investment strategies for every \(t \in \left[ 0,T \right] \).

  2. The authors, in their last section “Extensions and ramifications”, pp. 804–805, allow for random constrained regions but under additional strong conditions.

  3. For Figs. 1, 2 and 3 the same parameters as in Sect. 3.4 have been used with initial RALC 0.5.

  4. The values have been determined considering mean durations in EIOPA (2013).

  5. All numerical computations in this paper have been computed on a standard PC with an Intel i7 CPU, 2.30 GHz with cache size 5 MB. All codes are written in Matlab R2015a.

  6. All numerical computations in this paper have been computed on a standard PC with an Intel i7 CPU, 2.30 GHz with cache size 5 MB. All codes are written in Matlab R2015a.

References

  • Bauer, D., Bergmann, D., & Reuss, A. (2010). Solvency II and nested simulations—A least-squares Monte Carlo approach. In Proceedings of the ICA congress.

  • Bellman, R. (1957). Dynamic programming. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertsekas, D. P. (1995). Dynamic programming and optimal control (Vol. 1). Belmont: Athena Scientific. No. 2, Chapter 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Björk, T. (2009). Arbitrage theory in continuous time (p. 255). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun, A., Schmeiser, H., & Schreiber, F. (2015). Portfolio optimization under solvency II: Implicit constraints imposed by the market risk standard formula. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 82, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiansen, M., & Niemeyer, A. (2012). The fundamental definition of the solvency capital requirement in solvency II. Working Paper, Ulm University.

  • Cox, J. C., & Huang, C. (1989). Optimal consumption and portfolio policies when asset prices follow a diffusion process. Journal of Economic Theory, 49, 33–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cvitanić, J., & Karatzas, I. (1992). Convex duality in constrained portfolio optimization. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2, 767–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Soto, J. H. (2009). The fatal error of Solvency II. Economic Affairs, 29, 74–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devolder, P., & Lebègue, A. (2016). Risk measures versus ruin theory for the calculation of solvency capital for long-term life insurances. Dependence Modeling, 4(1), 306–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doff, R. (2008). A critical analysis of the Solvency II proposals. Risk Management and Insurance Review, 10, 69–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • EIOPA (2013). Technical findings on the long-term guarantees assessment appendix 1: Methodology for the calibration of the adaptation (CCP) (as tested in the assessment). EIOPA/13/297.

  • Eling, M., Schmeiser, H., & Schmit, J. T. (2007). The Solvency II process: Overview and critical analysis. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Issues and Practice, 33, 193–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Union (2009). Directive 2009/138/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 November 2009 on the taking-up and pursuit of the business of Insurance and Reinsurance (Solvency II). Official Journal of the European Union, L 335.

  • European Union (2015). Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2015/35 of 10 October 2014 supplementing Directive 2009/138/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on the taking-up and pursuit of the business of Insurance and Reinsurance (Solvency II) (1). Official Journal of the European Union, L12, Volume 58.

  • Fischer, K., & Schlütter, S. (2015). Optimal investment strategies for insurance companies when capital requirements are imposed by a standard formula. The Geneva Risk and Insurance Review, 40, 15–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fitch Ratings (2011). Solvency II set to reshape asset allocation and capital markets. Insurance Rating Group Special Report.

  • Gatzert, N., & Wesker, H. (2012). A comparative assessment of Basel II/III and Solvency II. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 37, 539–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He, H. (1990). Convergence from discrete-to continuous-time contingent claims prices. Review of Financial Studies, 3, 523–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höring, D. (2012). Will Solvency II market risk requirements bite? The impact of Solvency II on insurers’ asset allocation. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Issues and Practice, 38, 250–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hürlimann, W. (2009). On the non-life Solvency II model. In M. Cruz (Ed.), The Solvency II handbook, Chapter 13, risk books. London: Incisive Media.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J. P., & Shreve, S. E. (1987). Optimal portfolio and consumption decisions for a “small investor” on a finite horizon. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 25, 557–1586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kouwenberg, R. (2017). strategic asset allocation and risk budgeting for insurers under Solvency II. Working Paper, Mahidol University and Erasmus University Rotterdam.

  • Merton, R. (1969). Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51, 247–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mittnik, S. (2011). Solvency II calibrations: Where curiosity meets spuriosity, Working Paper.

  • Pfeifer, D., & Strassburger, D. (2008). Solvency II: Stability problems with the SCR aggregation formula. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2008, 61–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pliska, S. R. (1986). A stochastic calculus model of continuous trading: Optimal portfolios. Mathematics of Operations Research, 11, 371–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rieder, U., & Zagst, R. (1994). Monotonicity and bounds for convex stochastic control models. ZOR Methods and Models for Operation Research, 39, 187–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandström, A. (2007). Solvency II: Calibration for skewness. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2007, 126–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert, T. (2004). Solvency II = Basel II + X. Program on Regulation, Supervision and Legal Issues, 40 .

  • Steffen, T. (2008). Solvency II and the work of CEIOPS. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 33, 60–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zagst, R. (2002). Interest-rate management. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Zariphopoulou, T. (1994). Consumption-investment models with constraints. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 32, 59–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Markus Wahl and Rudi Zagst greatfully acknowledge the support of Allianz Global Investors for this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcos Escobar.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Let us assume that the Solvency II capital requirements for the different assets are positive, i.e.

$$\begin{aligned} SCR_i^{mkt}(t)= & {} \pi _i(t)k_i V_t> 0 \ \ \text{ for } i \in \left\{ \text{ equity, } \text{ real } \text{ estate, } \text{ spread } \right\} ,\\ SCR_{interest}^{mkt}(t)= & {} k_{interest} \left( d_L L - d_{interest} \ \pi _{interest} V_t - d_{spread} \ \pi _{spread} V_t \right) > 0 . \end{aligned}$$

The difference between the constraint sets \(\tilde{K}(c,t)\) and K(ct) is the vector \(\tilde{v}\) on the right-hand side of the inequality in the definition of the constraint set. Per definitionem it holds, that

$$\begin{aligned} v_1= & {} \frac{L}{V_t}d_L \le (1-c(t)) d_L := \tilde{v}_1\nonumber \\&\text{ with } \tilde{v}:= \left( (1-c(t)) d_L, 0, 0, 0\right) ^T . \end{aligned}$$
(30)

As the square root function is monotonously increasing and a composition of monotonously increasing functions is also monotonously increasing, let us consider the gradient

$$\begin{aligned}&\nabla g(v) \text{ with } g(v):= \left( B \pi (t) + v \right) ^T W C W \left( B \pi (t) + v \right) \\&\quad \nabla g(v) = 2 WCW (B \pi (t) + v). \end{aligned}$$

Since the matrix WCW is positive-definite \(\nabla g(v)\) is non-negative if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} B \pi (t) + v \ge 0 \Leftrightarrow \begin{pmatrix} d_L L - d_{interest} \ \pi _{interest}(t) V_t - d_{spread} \ \pi _{spread}(t) V_t \\ \pi _{equity}(t) \\ \pi _{realestate}(t) \\ \pi _{spread}(t) \\ \end{pmatrix} \ge \begin{pmatrix} 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ 0 \\ \end{pmatrix}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(31)

As we assumed that all \(SCR_i\) are positive, which is equivalent to inequality (31), the function

$$\begin{aligned} f(v):= \sqrt{\left( B \pi (t) + v \right) ^T W C W \left( B \pi (t) + v \right) } \end{aligned}$$

is monotonously increasing in v as a composition of monotonously increasing functions. Hence, using inequality (30), it holds

$$\begin{aligned} f(v) \le f(\tilde{v}). \end{aligned}$$

We can follow that

$$\begin{aligned} c(t) \ge f(\tilde{v}) \Rightarrow c(t) \ge f(v) , \end{aligned}$$

which concludes the statement

$$\begin{aligned} \pi \in \tilde{K}(c,t) \Rightarrow \pi \in K(c,t). \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Proof of Lemma 2

The support function of a convex set is defined as \(\delta (x,c,t):=\sup _{\pi \in K(c,t)}(-\pi ^Tx)\). Let \(t \in \left[ 0,T\right] \) and \(c(t)>0\) be fixed. Let x be inside the barrier cone \(X_{\tilde{K}}=\mathbb {R}^N\). We consider the Lagrangian function

$$\begin{aligned} L(\pi ,x)=-x^T \pi + l \left( c(t)^2- \left( B \pi + \tilde{v} \right) ^T WCW \left( B \pi + \tilde{v} \right) \right) \end{aligned}$$

with the Lagrange multiplier \(l \ge 0\). The two conditions are derived as

$$\begin{aligned} \nabla _{\pi }L(\pi ,x)=-x^T-2l \left( B \pi + \tilde{v} \right) ^T WCW B= 0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L}{\partial l}(\pi ,l)=c(t)^2- \left( B \pi + \tilde{v} \right) ^T WCW \left( B \pi + \tilde{v} \right) =0. \end{aligned}$$

From the first equation we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \pi = B^{-1} \left( -\frac{1}{2l} (WCW)^{-1} (B^T)^{-1} x - \tilde{v} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

where we implicitly used \(l>0\). The second condition then becomes

$$\begin{aligned} c(t)^2- \left( -\frac{1}{2l} (WCW)^{-1} (B^T)^{-1} x \right) ^T WCW \left( -\frac{1}{2l} (WCW)^{-1} (B^T)^{-1} x \right) = 0 \end{aligned}$$

and thus

$$\begin{aligned} l=\frac{1}{2c(t)}\left( x^T B^{-1} (WCW)^{-1} (B^T)^{-1} x\right) ^{\frac{1}{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Now we can conclude again using the symmetry of \(\left( WCW \right) ^{-1}\) that

$$\begin{aligned} \delta (x,c,t)=\sup _{\pi \in K(c,t)}(-\pi ^Tx)= c(t) \sqrt{x^T B^{-1} (WCW)^{-1} (B^T)^{-1}x} + x^T B^{-1}\tilde{v}. \end{aligned}$$

1.3 Proof of Example 1

First we compute the support function of the set \(K(c,t)=\left\{ \pi (t): c(t) \ge |\pi (t) k| \right\} \) by considering two cases.

$$\begin{aligned} \delta (c,x,t):=\sup _{\pi \in K(c,t)}(-\pi x) \end{aligned}$$

Case 1: \(x \ge 0\)

$$\begin{aligned} \sup _{\pi \in K(c,t)}(-\pi x)=\frac{c(t)}{k}x \end{aligned}$$

Case 2: \(x \le 0\)

$$\begin{aligned} \sup _{\pi \in K(c,t)}(-\pi x)=-\frac{c(t)}{k}x \end{aligned}$$

Combining the two cases we see

$$\begin{aligned} \delta (c,x,t)=\frac{c(t)}{k} | x | \end{aligned}$$

The optimal dual is calculated by considering the same two cases.

Case 1: \(x \ge 0\)

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^*(c,t)= \text {arg}\inf \limits _{x \in X_{K}} \left\{ c(t) \frac{x}{k}+\frac{1}{2}\left( \tilde{\gamma }+\frac{x}{\sigma }\right) ^2(\rho +1)\right\} \end{aligned}$$

In order to find the infimum, the derivative of \(f(x):= c(t) \frac{x}{k}+\frac{1}{2}(\tilde{\gamma }+\frac{x}{\sigma })^2(\rho +1)\) is set equal to 0

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{c(t)}{k}+ \left( \tilde{\gamma }+\sigma ^{-1}x\right) \sigma ^{-1} (\rho +1) = 0\\&\quad \Rightarrow x= - \frac{c(t) \sigma ^2}{k (\rho +1)}-(\mu -r) \end{aligned}$$

As we defined \(c(t) \ge 0\) and \(\mu \ge r\) it holds \(x<0\), which violates the assumption of Case 1. As the value function \(c(t)\frac{x}{k}+\frac{1}{2}( \tilde{\gamma }+\frac{x}{\sigma })^2(\rho +1)\) is strictly increasing for \(x>- \frac{c(t) \sigma ^2}{k (\rho +1)}-(\mu -r)\) the solution satisfying the condition of Case 1 is found to be \(x=0\).

Case 2: \(x \le 0\)

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^*(c,t)= \text {arg} \inf \limits _{x \in X_{K}} \left\{ -c(t) \frac{x}{k}+\frac{1}{2}\left( \tilde{\gamma }+\frac{x}{\sigma }\right) ^2(\rho +1)\right\} \end{aligned}$$

In order to find the infimum, the derivative of \(f(x):= -c(t) \frac{x}{k}+\frac{1}{2}(\tilde{\gamma }+\frac{x}{\sigma })^2(\rho +1)\) is set equal to 0

$$\begin{aligned}&-\frac{c(t)}{k}+\left( \tilde{\gamma }+\sigma ^{-1}x\right) \sigma ^{-1} (\rho +1) = 0\\&\quad \Rightarrow x= \frac{c(t) \sigma ^2}{k (\rho +1)}-(\mu -r) \end{aligned}$$

This solution fulfills the condition of Case 2, if

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{c(t) \sigma ^2}{k (\rho +1)} \le (\mu -r) \end{aligned}$$

If this does not hold true the optimal solution is again \(x=0\) as the value function is strictly decreasing for \(0 \le \frac{c(t) \sigma ^2}{k (\rho +1)}-(\mu -r) \).

Combining the two cases, it holds

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^*(c,t)= min \left( \frac{c(t)(1-\alpha ) \sigma ^2}{k}- (\mu - r),0 \right) \end{aligned}$$

Using the result from Chapter 2, the optimal investment strategy is found as

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^*_{\lambda ^*}(c,t)= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha }(\sigma )^{-1} \tilde{\gamma }_{\lambda ^*}= \frac{1}{1-\alpha }(\sigma )^{-1} ( \tilde{\gamma }(t)+\sigma ^{-1}\lambda ^*(c,t))\\= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha } (\sigma ^2)^{-1}( \mu - r + \lambda ^*(c,t) )\\= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha } (\sigma ^2)^{-1}\left( \mu - r + min \left( \frac{c(1-\alpha ) \sigma ^2}{k}- (\mu - r),0 \right) \right) \\= & {} min \left( \frac{c(t)}{k}, \frac{1}{1-\alpha } \frac{\mu -r}{\sigma ^2} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

1.4 Proof of Proposition 3

In Sect. 3 it has been shown, that for a constant c the wealth process \(V^*_t(c)\) behaves like a Geometric Brownian motion with constant drift and diffusion

$$\begin{aligned} dV_t^*(c)= & {} V_t^*(c) \left[ ((\pi ^*(c))^T (\mu -r)+r) dt + (\pi ^*(c))^T \sigma dW_t \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Due to the exponential structure of the solution of the SDE, the minimum of such a Geometric Brownian motion can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} min V^*_{t}(c) = V^*_{0}(c) e^{min R_t} = V_0 e^{min R_t} , \end{aligned}$$

where \(R_t= \tilde{\mu }t + \tilde{\sigma }W_t\) is a Wiener process with drift \(\tilde{\mu }\) and diffusion \(\tilde{\sigma }\)

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\mu }= ((\pi ^*(c))^T (\mu -r)+r) - \frac{(\Vert (\pi ^*(c))^T \sigma \Vert )^2}{2} \quad \text{ and } \quad \tilde{\sigma }= \Vert (\pi ^*(c))^T \sigma \Vert . \end{aligned}$$

Analyzing the distribution of the RALC process, we find

$$\begin{aligned}&\mathbb {P} \left[ \underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} \frac{V^*_{t}(c)-L}{V^*_{t}(c)} \ge c \right] = \mathbb {P} \left[ \underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} \left( 1-L \frac{1}{V^*_{t}(c)}\right) \ge c \right] \\&\quad = \mathbb {P} \left[ 1- L \underset{0 \le t \le T}{max} \left( \frac{1}{V^*_{t}(c)}\right) \ge c \right] \\&\quad = \mathbb {P} \left[ \underset{0 \le t \le T}{max} \left( \frac{1}{V^*_{t}(c)}\right) \le \frac{1-c}{L} \right] = \mathbb {P} \left[ \frac{1}{\underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} \left( V^*_{t}(c)\right) } \le \frac{1-c}{L} \right] \\&\quad =\mathbb {P} \left[ \frac{L}{1-c} \le \underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} V^*_{t}(c) \right] \\&\quad =1-\mathbb {P} \left[ \underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} V^*_{t}(c) \le \frac{L}{1-c} \right] =1-\mathbb {P} \left[ V_0 e^{min R_t} \le \frac{L}{1-c} \right] \\&\quad =1-\mathbb {P} \left[ \underset{0 \le t \le T}{min} R_t \le \log \left( \frac{L}{1-c} \frac{1}{V_0}\right) \right] \\&\quad = 1-N \left( \frac{\log \left( \frac{L}{(1-c)V_{0}} \right) - \tilde{\mu }T}{\tilde{\sigma } \sqrt{T}}\right) - e^{2\frac{\log \left( \frac{L}{(1-c)V_{0}}\right) \tilde{\mu }}{\tilde{\sigma }^2}} N \left( \frac{\log \left( \frac{L}{(1-c)V_{0}}\right) +\tilde{\mu }T}{\tilde{\sigma } \sqrt{T}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where the distribution function of the running minimum of \(R_t\) is taken from Björk (2009), p. 209.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Escobar, M., Kriebel, P., Wahl, M. et al. Portfolio optimization under Solvency II. Ann Oper Res 281, 193–227 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2835-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2835-x

Keywords

Navigation