Intra-Regional Trade and Regional Exposure to the Global Economy: Implications for Cooperation and Conflict

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Turmoil and Order in Regional International Politics

Part of the book series: Evidence-Based Approaches to Peace and Conflict Studies ((EBAPCS,volume 10))

  • 155 Accesses

Abstract

Despite the bourgeoning field of political economy and the substantial emphasis on the Kantian peace, there has been very little systematic research on the extent to which regions begin to lose their autonomy under extensive trade globalization. While trade has been a significant concern in monadic and dyadic studies of conflict and peace, it has not been studied in a similar manner at the regional level. In this chapter we explore (a) some of the reasons why this is the case; (b) suggest some empirical mechanisms through which obstacles to analysis can be overcome; and (c) trace the pattern of trade relations within regions and within the global trading system. We differentiate between degrees of trade integration within regions (intra-regional trade) versus regional dependence (loss of regional autonomy) on global trade patterns (extra-regional trade). We conclude with some consequences for peace and conflict within and between regions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
EUR 32.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or Ebook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free ship** worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    We measure trade as (exports + imports)/2.

  2. 2.

    Including Belarus, Moldova, Serbia, Russian Federation, Georgia, Azerbaijan, Armenia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Uzbekistan, and Turkmenistan. We exclude those states that are members of the EU or if they had established a path to EU membership prior to 2020.

  3. 3.

    As another point of comparison, Hungary’s exports, an EU member but with friendly relations with the Kremlin, had, by 2018, exceeded Ukrainian exports to Russia.

  4. 4.

    As some have argued (Bell & Long, 2016; Copeland, 1996) when the expectation is that trade relations are on the decline, it may make the use of force more appealing to policymakers. This would be even more the case here since declining trade relations have been part and parcel of Russian paranoia about losing its sphere of influence in the “near-abroad”.

  5. 5.

    For recent reviews of the trade-conflict literature, see Chan (2021), Lee and Pyun (2016), Lupu and Traag (2012), Peterson and Zeng (2021), Bell and Long (2016). For an earlier review, see Cornwell and Colaresi (2002).

  6. 6.

    Including whether trade relations are asymmetrical, dependent or interdependent, and whether the focus should be on contiguous or major trading partners.

  7. 7.

    For a few exceptions, see Lupu and Traag (2012) (who develop the concept of trading communities that appear to approximate regions), Kim and Shin (2002), and Allen (2018). Lee and Pyun (2016) also find that the effects of dyadic trade are most clearly felt when states are proximate, implying a regional context to trade relationships.

  8. 8.

    The approach allows states and regions to vary over time. However, making intra-regional comparisons when regions and their membership change make such comparisons virtually impossible. We make two exceptions to reflect changing political circumstance. First, European states are kept at two classifications: Western Europe and “Eastern Europe”. The latter, along with the creation of a Central Asian region, has no valid data prior to the end of the Cold War. In the case of Central Asia, most of those states were part of the USSR. In the case of Eastern Europe, prior to the Cold War, either states were part of the USSR (the Baltics, Georgia, Armenia, etc.), part of the former Yugoslavia (Serbia), or lacked meaningful trade and GDP data (e.g., Poland, Czechoslovakia, Bulgaria). We designate East Europe to include all states that were part of the former Soviet Union and had neither formal application to NATO nor to the EU for membership as of 2020. The other “eastern” European states are then designated as part of Western Europe (e.g., Hungary, Poland, etc.).

  9. 9.

    Available at https://wits.worldbank.org/countrystats.aspx?lang=en.

  10. 10.

    We merged the Gleditsch data (1948–2000) with the World Bank WITS data (2001–2020). For the World Bank WITS data, we filled missing values in the imports/exports with the exports/imports reported by the counterparty where available. The Gleditsch data does not have any missing values. The correlation between the two data sets for years when we had overlap was approximately 0.97. Next, we aggregated the trade data into a “country-year” format to obtain the total trade amount of each country each year. We measure total trade amount as (gross imports + gross exports)/2. Finally, we added GDP figures (1960–2020) for all countries in current dollars using the World Bank database. Because the World Bank data does not include Taiwan, we added Taiwanese GDP data from the IMF database.

  11. 11.

    Data on GDP are from the World Bank.

  12. 12.

    The one exception is during the 1990s, during which German unification was taking place along with a gradual integration of former East European states with the European community.

  13. 13.

    After apartheid, intra-regional and all trade as a percent of regional GDP in Southern Africa had doubled (Fig. 16).

  14. 14.

    Our network-based community detection procedure for the 2010–2019 timeframe indicates that between them, the fifteen states of the region cluster with no fewer than eight different trading communities, suggesting that not only is intra-regional trade low, but likely are also indirect intra-regional trading partners outside of the region.

  15. 15.

    The region includes the Russian Federation and its possible allies in East Europe and the Caucuses, consisting of states that were formerly part of the USSR, and as of 2020, are neither in the application process nor have been granted membership in either NATO or the European Union, including Ukraine.

  16. 16.

    Although that trend reverses somewhat in during the 2010s.

  17. 17.

    Following Kim and Shin (2002), we adjusted trade network ties for inflation and output growth, and then used only those ties having amounts greater than $10 million to calculate densities. For a given region, the regional density is defined as the ratio of the number of observed ties to the number of theoretically possible ties between regional members.

  18. 18.

    To quantify the overlap, we identify for each geopolitical region subsets of countries belonging to the same trade community, and we measure the share of the biggest subset.

  19. 19.

    The Western European case underscores another utility for the community detection measure: it can show how states newly integrated into a region are contributing to or detracting from its relative economic interdependence. In the Western European case, the detection measure shows that virtually all the Central European states that were previously in the East European region during the Cold War, or were not independent states (e.g., the Baltics, Slovakia, or the states emerging from the dissolution of Yugoslavia) but joined the Western European region after the Cold War, by 2016 cluster together with the rest of the dominant grou** for Western Europe.

  20. 20.

    Under certain conditions it may be plausible to have more than one dominant power residing in the region, as is the case in Western Europe (the UK, France, and Germany), where the potential for conflict between them can erase intra-regional trade benefits for cooperation. What appears to be important, however, is that all the dominant powers in residence benefit substantially from intra-regional trade relationships.

  21. 21.

    It is not our purpose here to treat trade as a dependent variable and to account for conditions likely to increase or deflate intra-regional trade.

  22. 22.

    The table treats cooperation and conflict as two separate dimensions, based on the assumption that states (e.g., Peterson & Zeng, 2021), and especially states within the same region engage in both types of relationships simultaneously. As we note below, this appears to be the case both for East Asia and Eastern Europe.

  23. 23.

    Available at https://transresearchconsortium.com/.

  24. 24.

    Our analysis underscores a strong difference between dyadic versus region level approaches to studying the effects of trade on conflict and cooperation. While substantial numbers of dyads in international politics pass the threshold we suggest are necessary for their trade relationship to have a positive effect on cooperation, at the regional level only four of the fourteen regions appear to meet the first criterion of having high levels of intra-regional trade during the 2010s, and only three do so during the 2000s. Conducting inquiry at the regional level creates fewer cases and more research design complexity for analysts than a dyadic level of analysis of trade and its conflict/cooperation consequences. No wonder then that so little scholarship focuses on the regional level.

  25. 25.

    We do not assume a linear relationship between trade and cooperation since we don’t expect incremental changes in trade relationships to yield similar changes in cooperation. Instead, we suggest that the most likely effects occur when a certain sufficiently high threshold value is crossed in the trade relationship, one which can create substantial costs for actions that may negatively impact trading partners.

  26. 26.

    We assess “benefits” from intra-regional trade on the part of dominant powers residing in the region in terms of whether such dominant powers are engaged in intra-regional trade levels that are substantially below the norm of their region’s intra-regional trade. Substantially lower levels of intra-regional trade by the dominant power would suggest that for it, intra-regional trade is less consequential than for other members of the region.

  27. 27.

    The correlation between a region’s intra-regional trade in one decade and its intra-regional trade in the previous decade is 0.95.

  28. 28.

    Nevertheless, the longitudinal data for East Europe further underscore the possibility that the dramatic decline in the region’s intra-regional trade may have contributed to the hostilities between Russia and Ukraine, both in 2014 and 2022.

  29. 29.

    For a similar approach but at the dyadic level of analysis, and using exports rather than exposure, see Mousseau (2019).

  30. 30.

    This threshold is at half of the highest level of dependency exhibited in the figure by the Maghreb region.

  31. 31.

    The correlation between level of global market dependence and regional wealth is −0.21.

  32. 32.

    We smooth out annual fluctuations by averaging values across each decade for all substantive variables.

  33. 33.

    The adjusted R squared value for the model, incorporating only three variables, is also quite high at 71%.

  34. 34.

    The Biden administration’s Build Back Better World, the G7’s Partnership for Global Infrastructure and Investment program (The Economist 2022b), and the EU’s Global Gateway infrastructure-for-Africa plan (The Economist 2022c) are meant to counter China’s initiatives.

  35. 35.

    Note for instance that despite the intense rivalry between China and Taiwan, Taiwanese trade with China represents roughly 45% of its total trade (in 2021).

References

  • Aaron, A. (2022, June 20). Berlin is having second thoughts about its trade dependence on China. World Politics Review. https://www.worldpoliticsreview.com/articles/30622/berlin-reconsiders-merkel-s-approach-to-germany-china-relations

  • Allen, M. A. (2018). The influence of regional power distributions on interdependence. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 62(5), 1072–1099.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Associated Press. (2022, June 22). China hosts BRICS meeting amid rising economic concerns. https://www.staradvertiser.com/2022/06/22/breaking-news/china-hosts-brics-meeting-amid-rising-economic-concerns/

  • Aydin, A. (2008). Choosing sides: Economic interdependence and interstate disputes. Journal of Politics, 70(4), 1098–1108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M. A., Anton, S., & Voeten, E. (2015). Estimating dynamic state preferences from United Nations voting data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 61(2), 430–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbieri, K. (2002). The liberal illusion: Does trade promote peace? University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bell, S., & Long, A. G. (2016). Trade interdependence and the use of force: Do issues matter? International Interactions, 42(5), 750–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, D., Bond, J., & Oh, C. (2003). Integrated data for events analysis (idea): An event typology for automated events data development. Journal of Peace Research, 40(6), 733–745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, F. R. (2021). Extended dependence: Trade, alliances, and peace. Journal of Politics, 83(1), 246–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, D. C. (1996). Economic interdependence and war: A theory of trade expectations. International Security, 20(1), 5–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornwell, D., & Colaresi, M. (2002). Holy trinities, rivalry termination, and conflict. International Interactions, 28(4), 325–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorussen, H., & Ward, H. (2010). Trade networks and the Kantian peace. Journal of Peace Research, 47(1), 29–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gatzke, E., & Li, Q. (2003). War, peace, and the invisible hand: Positive political externalities of economic globalization. International Studies Quarterly, 47(4), 561–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gartzke, E., Quan, L., & Boehmer, C. (2001). Investing in the peace: Economic interdependence and international conflict. International Organization, 55 (2), 391–438.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gartzke, E., & Westerwinter, O. (2016). The complex structure of commercial peace contrasting trade interdependence, asymmetry, and multipolarity. Journal of Peace Research, 53(3), 325–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, K. S. (2002). Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5), 712–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, B. E. (2013). International trade and the onset and escalation of interstate conflict: More to fight About, or more reasons not to fight? Defence and Peace Economics, 24(6), 555–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J. S. (1992). A conflict-cooperation scale for WEIS events data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 36(2), 369–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haim, D. A. (2016). Alliance networks and trade: The effect of indirect political alliances on bilateral trade flow. Journal of Peace Research, 53(3), 472–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hille, K. (2022, May 26). China builds coalition to counter America’s ‘barbaric and bloody’ leadership. Financial Times. https://www.ft.com/content/377cdb02-8a45-4ba2-b6ee-88620eb48f0b

  • Kim, S., & Shin, E.-H. (2002). A longitudinal analysis of globalization and regionalization in international trade. Social Forces, 81(2), 445–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinne, B. J. (2012). Multilateral trade and militarized conflict: Centrality, openness, and asymmetry in the global trade network. Journal of Politics, 74(1), 308–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleinberg, K. B., Robinson, G., & French, S. L. (2012). Trade concentration and interstate conflict. Journal of Politics, 74(2), 529–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake, D. A. (2007). Regional hierarchy: Authority and local international order. Review of International Studies, 35(1), 35–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, H., & Rider, T. J. (2018). Evaluating the effects of trade on militarized behavior in the context of territorial threat. Foreign Policy Analysis, 14(1), 44–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J.-W., & Pyun, J. H. (2016). Does trade integration contribute to peace? Review of Development Economics, 20(1), 327–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q., & Reuveny, R. (2011). Does trade prevent or promote interstate conflict? Journal of Peace Research, 48(4), 437–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lupu, Y., & Traag, V. A. (2012). Trading communities, the networked structure of international relations, and the Kantian peace. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(6), 1011–1042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrow, J. D. (1999). How could trade affect conflict? Journal of Peace Research, 36(4), 481–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mousseau, M. (2019). The end of war: How a robust marketplace and liberal hegemony Are leading to perpetual world peace. International Security, 44(1), 160–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M. E. (2006). Modularity and community structure in networks. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 103(23), 8577–8582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oneal, J. R., & Russett, B. M. (1997). Assessing the liberal peace with alternative specifications: Trade still reduces conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 36(3), 423–442.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, T. M., & Zeng, Y. (2021). Conflict and cooperation with trade partners. International Interactions, 47(2), 266–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. (2004). Interdependence theory and the measurement of international conflict. Journal of Politics, 66(1), 247–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polachek, S., & **ang J. (2010). How opportunity costs decrease the probability of war in an incomplete information game. International Organization, 64(1), 133–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhamey, J. P. (2012). Constrained to cooperate: Domestic political capacity and regional order. PhD dissertation, University of Arizona. Accessed on ProQuest/UMI (Publication Number 3505997).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosecrance, R. N. (1986). The rise of the trading state: Commerce and conquest in the modern world. Basic Books, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakuwa, K. (2018). Approaches to explaining regional conflict and peace. In W. R. Thompson (Ed.), The Oxford Encyclopedia of empirical international relations theory. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shalal, A. (2022, June 26). G7 aims to raise $600 billion to counter China’s belt and road. Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/world/refile-us-aims-raise-200-bln-part-g7-rival-chinas-belt-road-2022-06-26/

  • Stopford, J., & Strange, S. (1991). Rival states, rival firms: Competition for world market shares. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • The Economist. (2022a, January 8). African economies: When you are in a hole…how Africa can reduce its reliance on commodities. Economist, pp. 39–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Economist. (2022b, July 9). Global infrastructure investment: building blocs. Economist, pp. 35–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Economist. (2022c, May 26). Countering China in Africa. Economist. https://www.economist.com/special-report/2022/05/20/countering-china-in-africa

  • Thompson, W. R., Volgy, T. J., et al. (2022). Regions, power and conflict: Constrained capabilities, hierarchy, and rivalry. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Voeten, E. (2019). Data and analyses of voting in the UN General Assembly. In B. Reinalda (Ed.), Routledge handbook of international organization. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volgy, T. J., Bezerra, P., Cramer, J., & Rhamey, J. P. (2017). The case for comparative regional analysis in international politics. International Studies Review, 19(3), 452–480.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volgy, T. J., Gordell, K. M., Bezerra, P., & Rhamey, J. P. (2018). Conflict, regions, and regional hierarchies. In W. R. Thompson (Ed.), Oxford research encyclopedia of empirical international relations theory. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas J. Volgy .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix A: Regions and state membership

NORTH AMERICA

SOUTH AMERICA

US

Argentina

Canada

Bolivia

Mexico

Brazil

MAGHREB

Chile

Algeria

Colombia

Libya

Ecuador

Morocco

Guyana

Tunisia

Peru

MIDDLE EAST

Uruguay

Bahrain

Venezuela

Egypt

EAST ASIA

Iran

China

Iraq

Japan

Israel

South Korea

Jordan

North Korea

Kuwait

Mongolia

Lebanon

Taiwan

Oman

SOUTH ASIA

Qatar

Afghanistan

Saudi Arabia

Bangladesh

Syria

Bhutan

Turkey

India

United Arab Emirates (UAE)

Maldives

Yemen

Nepal

Yemen

Pakistan Sri Lanka

SOUTHEAST ASIA

CENTRAL ASIA (begins in 1992)

Brunei

Kazakhstan

Cambodia

Kyrgyzstan

Indonesia

Uzbekistan

Laos

Tajikistan

Malaysia

Turkmenistan

Myanmar

Western Europe additions (beginning 1992)

Philippines

Albania

Singapore

Bosnia

Thailand

Bulgaria

Vietnam

Croatia

WESTERN EUROPE

Czech Republic (Chechia)

Austria

Estonia

Belgium

Hungary

Cyprus

Latvia

Denmark

Lithuania

Finland

North Macedonia

France

Montenegro

Germany

Poland

Greece

Romania

Ireland

Serbia

Iceland

Slovakia

Italy

Slovenia

Luxembourg

EAST EUROPE (Beginning 1992)

Netherlands

Armenia

Norway

Azerbaijan

Portugal

Belarus

Spain

Georgia

Sweden

Moldova

Switzerland

Ukraine

United Kingdom

Russian Federation

WEST AFRICA

SOUTHERN AFRICA

Benin

Angola

Burkina Faso

Botswana

Cameroon

Lesotho

Cape Verde

Mozambique

Cote D’Ivoire

Namibia

Gambia

South Africa

Ghana

Swaziland (Eswatini)

Guinea

Zambia

Guinea-Bissau

Zimbabwe

Liberia

CENTRAL AFRICA

Mali

Burundi

Niger

Central African Republic

Nigeria

Democratic Republic of the Congo

Senegal

Republic of Congo

Sierra Leone

Rwanda

Togo

Chad

EAST AFRICA

 

Djibuti

 

Eritrea

 

Ethiopia

 

Kenya

 

South Sudan

 

Somalia

 

Sudan

 

Tanzania

 

Uganda

 

Appendix B: Intra-regional and global trade patterns by regions, 1960s–2010s

See Figs. 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20, 21, and 22.

Fig. 9
A double bar graph denotes intra-regional and global trade patterns in Western Europe from 1960 through 2010. The intra-regional percentage is high in the 1980s whereas G D P is high in the 2010s. The values are approximate.

W. Europe, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, in percentages, 1960–2020

Fig. 10
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in North America from the 1960s and the 2010s. The intra-regional trade ranges between 30 and 45 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P increases throughout the years. The values are approximate.

North America, intra-REGIONAL trade/all trade, and all trade/GDP, in percentages, 1960–2020

Fig. 11
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in South Eastern Asia from 1960 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 10 and 25 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest in 2000 followed by 1990 and the lowest is in 1960. The values are approximate.

SE Asia, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/GDP, in percentages, 1960–2019

Fig. 12
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in East Asia from 1960 to 2010. The percentage of inter-regional trade is at its maximum in the 1960s and 30% in 2000. The percentage of G D P dominates the inter-regional trade and reaches 30% in 2010. The values are approximate.

East Asia, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/GDP, in percentages, 1960–2019

Fig. 13
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in East Africa from 1970 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 5 and 10 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest in 1970 followed by 2000. The values are approximate.

East Africa, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, 1970–2019

Fig. 14
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in Central Africa from 1970 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 0 and 5 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest of 70% in 1970 followed by 45% in 2010 and the lowest at 35% in 2000. The values are approximate.

Central Africa, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, 1970–2019

Fig. 15
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in West Africa from 1970 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 0 and 10 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest of 43% in 1970 and its lowest at 30% in 1980. The values are approximate.

West Africa, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, in Percentages, 1970–2019

Fig. 16
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in Southern Africa from 1970 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 5 and 20 throughout the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest at 50% in 2010 and the lowest at 29% in 1990. The values are approximate.

Southern Africa, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, in Percentages, 1970–2020

Fig. 17
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in Maghreb from 1960 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 0 and 5 throughout the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest of 65% in 2010 and the lowest at 50% in 2000. The values are approximate.

Maghreb, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, in percentages, 1960–2020

Fig. 18
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P trade patterns in South Eastern Asia from 1960 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 5 and 15 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P is at its highest of 50% in 2010 followed by 45% in 2000 and the lowest at 37% in 1960. The values are approximate.

Middle East, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/region GDP, in percentages, 1960–2020

Fig. 19
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in South Asia from 1960 to 2010. The intra-regional trade percentage ranges between 0 and 5 throughout all the years. The percentage of G D P increases throughout the years, its highest percentage is 35% in 2010, and the lowest at 13% in 1960. The values are approximate.

South Asia, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/GDP in percentages, 1960–2019

Fig. 20
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in Central Asia from 1960 to 2010. There is no data for both till the 1980s. From the 1990s through the 2010s, the inter-regional trade percentage ranged between 0 and 8 whereas G D P ranges between 45 and 60. The highest G D P is in 2000. The values are approximate.

Central Asia, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/GDP in percentages, 1990s-2019

Fig. 21
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in Eastern Europe from the 1960s and the 2010s. There is no data for both till the 1980s. From the 1990s through the 2010s, the inter-regional trade percentage ranged between 18 and 30, with its maximum in the 1990s. The highest value of G D P is 40% in the 2000s followed by the 1990s and 2010s. The values are approximate.

“Eastern Europe”, intra-regional trade/all trade, all trade/GDP, in percentages, 1990s-2019

Fig. 22
A double bar graph denotes the inter-regional and G D P patterns in South America from the 1960s to the 2010s. The highest percentage for intra-regional trade is in the 2000s. The highest percentage for G D P is in the 2010s.

South America, intra-regional trade/all trade and all trade/GDP in percentages, 1960–2019

Appendix C: Density of intra-regional network, 1986, 1996, 2006, and 2016

Year

1986

1996

2006

2016

North America

1.000

1.000

1.000

1.000

South America

0.591

0.645

0.673

0.673

Maghreb

0.667

0.833

0.833

0.667

Middle East

0.562

0.486

0.667

0.667

East Asia

0.600

0.667

0.533

0.467

South Asia

0.286

0.286

0.375

0.429

Southeast Asia

0.400

0.533

0.689

0.689

Central Asia

0.750

0.500

0.500

Western Europe

0.434

0.635

0.784

0.760

Eastern Europe

0.619

0.667

0.667

West Africa

0.142

0.138

0.163

0.138

Southern Africa

0.139

0.194

0.333

0.347

Central Africa

0.033

0.067

East Africa

0.143

0.250

0.196

0.196

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Yoon, E., Volgy, T.J. (2023). Intra-Regional Trade and Regional Exposure to the Global Economy: Implications for Cooperation and Conflict. In: Thompson, W.R., Volgy, T.J. (eds) Turmoil and Order in Regional International Politics. Evidence-Based Approaches to Peace and Conflict Studies, vol 10. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-99-0557-7_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics

Navigation